Issue 1 | April 2024 ISBN 978-92-68-14914-0, ISSN: 2315-3113
Competition policy brief
KD-AK-24-001-EN-N, doi 10.2763/67590
©European Union, 2024
Reproduction is authorised provided the source is acknowledged.
More publications on: https://ec.europa.eu/competition-policy/publications_en and http://bookshop.europa.eu
Page 1 Non-Price Competition: EU Merger Control Framework and
Case Practice
Page 16 Assessing Innovation Competition in Pharma Mergers
This issue focuses on non-price competition in EU merger control:
The content of this article does not necessarily reflect the
official position of the European Commission. Responsibility
for the information and views expressed lies entirely with
the authors.
Competition Policy Brief
Non-Price Competition: EU Merger
Control Framework and Case Practice
Alexander Iken, Terézia Kianičková, Marion Bailly, Andrea Usai,
Gabor Koltay, Stephan Simon
Introduction - Why looking at non-price
competition?
Mergers are long-run events that may affect important
parameters of competition. Besides prices, transactions can
influence available products and services, or change their quality
and variety. Mergers might also influence the merging firms’
production processes, technologies, and capacities. These
changes might become effective immediately or only in the more
distant future. But they can have profound competitive
implications and the assessment of non-price parameters of
competition has been gaining an increasing prominence in merger
reviews by the European Commission.
In the EU, the competitive process is at the centre of the
assessment of the effects of mergers. The Commission applies a
broad “consumer welfare” standard, which focuses on preventing
harm to the competitive process, thus ensuring competitive
outcomes to the benefit of consumers. The notion of “consumers”
is wide, encompassing not just end-consumers, but also
customers at upstream levels of the value chain, including large
and small companies that act as consumers in various markets
and business transactions and that may suffer from competition
harm. This standard therefore applies regardless of which
parameters of competition may be adversely affected by a
merger. Consumer welfare depends directly on non-price aspects
of competition, such as variety, quality and availability of
products and services. The Commission’s scrutiny of harm to
consumers includes harm to the competitive process and is
integral to the significant impediment to effective competition
(“SIEC”) test under the EU Merger Regulation (“EUMR”)
1
.
1
Council Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 of 20 January 2004 on the
control of concentrations between undertakings, OJ L 24, 29.1.2004,
p.1.
To be clear, while the
Commission pursues a
consumer-centred
enforcement approach, it
does not go beyond a
competition-related
consumer welfare standard.
Merger control is part of EU
competition policy, and
while it can contribute to
other EU objectives, it does
not typically address other
societal goals if they are
not related to competitive
processes.
2
Parameters of competition
typically correspond to the
characteristics of the (final)
products and services
valued by consumers, for
instance price, quality,
innovation, environmental
impact, and the protection
of personal data and
privacy. But they are not
limited to those: relevant
parameters of competition
also encompass
(intermediary) processes
which reflect the companies’ longer-term business decisions (e.g.,
capacity, R&D efforts, capital expenditures) that will ultimately
affect the products and services offered to consumers in the
medium to long term.
2
For example, competition enforcement may impact labour conditions to
the extent that anticompetitive conduct occurs on labour markets.
Labour markets have thus been investigated in antitrust cases, notably
with respect to wage-fixing and no-poach agreements. At the national
level, the Hungarian and Portuguese competition authorities have
imposed fines for antitrust infringements in no-poach agreements
(case references VJ/61/2017 (Hungary) and PRC/2020/1 (Portugal)).
Similarly, the Commission is looking to investigate anti-competitive
conduct in labour markets (Speech by Margrethe Vestager at the Italian
Antitrust Association Annual Conference, "A new era of cartel
enforcement", on 22 October 2021).
Non-Price Competition: EU Merger Control Framework and Case Practice |
Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
2
Consumers have always and will continue to put an important
weight on price as a parameter of competition. Nevertheless,
assessing the impact of a merger beyond (short term) effects on
prices allows for the capture of the negative effects for
consumers on all the parameters that matter to their purchasing
decisions. It thus seeks to prevent a structural negative impact of
a merger in the longer term. Non-price effects of horizontal
mergers amplify negative consequences for consumers through
reduced competition and compound price increases.
3
From a legal standpoint, EU law does not pose any obstacles to
assessing the non-price effects of mergers. The EUMR's
substantive test does not preclude the Commission from
considering any particular type of effect on competition that a
merger may bring. Furthermore, the Horizontal Merger
Guidelines
4
indicate that it is not only the ability of the merged
entity to profitably increase prices, but also to reduce output,
choice or quality of goods and services, diminish innovation, or
otherwise influence parameters of competition negatively in a
significant way that could lead to an intervention by the
Commission. The EUMR thus provides a flexible framework that
allows the Commission to assess competition between the
merging parties and their rivals across a spectrum of parameters
that are relevant in a given market.
This brief will explore a number of aspects of the Commission’s
approach to assessing the non-price parameters of competition.
Section 1 provides a non-exhaustive overview of the type of
non-price parameters of competition that may be relevant in a
merger review, pointing to industries where the Commission
would find them particularly relevant. Section 2 explores where
and how non-price parameters may be taken into account in the
Commission’s assessment of mergers.
1. Which non-price parameters, and in
which industries?
The Commission’s assessment of non-price effects is conducted
on a case-by-case basis, taking into account the specificities of
markets, products, and customer behaviour. In its case practice,
the Commission has developed a non-exhaustive set of criteria to
establish whether a non-price parameter is relevant in a specific
industry or market.
1.1 Innovation
Innovation is the essential driver of economic progress that
benefits consumers, businesses, and the economy as a whole.
Innovation efforts range from incremental technological progress
to more radical changes in how markets function, for instance in
3
See e.g., Haucap/Stiebale, Non-price Effects of Mergers and
Acquisitions (DICE Discussion Paper 402, 2023), Section 1, paper
commissioned by the European Commission.
4
Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers under the Council
Regulation on the control of concentrations between undertakings, OJ C
31, 5.2.2004, p. 5 (“Horizontal Merger Guidelines”).
relation to renewable energy technologies and sources,
computer-integrated manufacturing, digital delivery of services,
and artificial intelligence.
Innovation requires competition. Undertakings normally have
an incentive to innovate to gain a competitive advantage to
capture sales away from each other and protect their existing
sales from each other. A merger may internalise this effect and
reduce the innovation incentive. In this case, the effects can be
thought of as standard unilateral effects, applied in this case to
innovation efforts rather than to prices or volumes. As a result,
mergers between rival innovators tend to reduce innovation
incentives, unless there are sufficient knowledge spillovers or
other efficiencies
5
Innovation-related harm to consumers manifests itself in three
ways (i) a discontinuation of existing pipeline products, (ii) a
reduction in future R&D efforts, and (iii) a reduction in future
product market competition. In its merger control practice, the
Commission has thus found innovation to be an important
competitive parameter in several industries, for example the
pharmaceutical, medical device, agrochemical, financial services,
and digital sector. Assessing the importance of innovation in a
certain industry or market requires a close look at its features
and structure.
Industries with a significant expenditure on R&D. A starting
point and first indicator of the relevance of innovation is the
amount of expenditure on R&D across a given market or industry.
In its review of Dow/DuPont, a merger between two agrochemical
companies, the Commission’s analysis of innovation effects relied
on the high costs of discovery and development for new active
ingredients in the crop protection industry (of USD 286 million
per active ingredient).
6
In General Electric/Alstom, the Commission
examined the transaction’s effects on innovation for heavy-duty
gas turbines, in part because of the high R&D spend, the need
for specialised engineers, and the high headcount for R&D
programmes across the industry.
7
When reviewing mergers in the
pharmaceutical industry the Commission also pays particular
attention to effects on innovation because of its important role in
the competitive process, as exemplified by the significant
expenditure on R&D.
8
Rapidly growing or evolving markets. Innovation plays a
particularly important role in markets or industries which are
rapidly growing or changing. This does not only apply to the areas
of IT and digital services, but can extend to all kinds of industries,
such as pharmaceuticals, manufacturing, transport, or energy.
5
G. Federico, "Horizontal Mergers, Innovation and the Competitive
Process”, Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, Volume 8,
Issue 10, December 2017, Pages 668677.
6
M.7932 Dow/DuPont, paragraph 242.
7
M.7278 General Electric/Alstom, paragraphs 385 387.
8
See for example M.7559 Pfizer/Hospira, paragraphs 55 56, where the
Commission observed development costs of up to EUR 400 million per
product (in this case a biosimilar).
Non-Price Competition: EU Merger Control Framework and Case Practice |
Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
3
In its recent review of the acquisition by Illumina, a supplier of
Next-Generation Sequencing technology (‘NGS’) for genetic and
genomic analysis, of GRAIL, a customer of Illumina using NGS
systems to develop cancer detection tests, the Commission found
innovation to be a key parameter in the markets where the
parties were active. The Commission noted that GRAIL and its
rivals were engaged in an innovation race to develop early cancer
detection tests. While there was still uncertainty about the exact
results of this innovation race and the future shape of the market
for NGS-based early cancer detection tests, it was expected to
expand rapidly and to become highly lucrative.
9
At the same time, the importance of innovation is assessed
individually for each market without presuming that certain
trends apply throughout a given industry. Not every ‘digital
market’ is necessarily characterised by a high level of innovation.
For example, in Apple/Shazam, the Commission’s market
investigation did not find, at that time, innovation to be a relevant
parameter in the market for dedicated music recognition apps for
smart mobile devices.
10
Industries where price plays a limited role. When
competition in a given market is not primarily based on price,
innovation can be a key parameter of competition. Examples
include the pharmaceutical industry and, more recently, digital
services. While pharmaceutical products have a substantial price
tag, their cost is often covered by insurances or national health
systems and not by prescribing doctors or patients. Efficacy, new
modes of action, new treatment options and other innovative
aspects often outweigh the importance of price as a parameter
of competition. Digital services, for their part, often do not require
any monetary payment from consumers and suppliers instead
compete by offering the most innovative, practical, or user-
friendly service.
Industries with a need’ for innovation. Certain products or
markets may require a certain level of innovation for purposes
other than the mere improvement of quality. For example, in
Dow/DuPont and Bayer/Monsanto, the Commission found that
innovation plays an important role in pesticide and herbicide
development due to the adaptation of certain weeds or insects to
existing products. Thus, innovation may be needed in these
markets to maintain a degree of effectiveness.
11
Similarly,
regulators might require suppliers to innovate. Thus, in
Dow/DuPont, the Commission found that, due to the growing
environmental and food safety requirements, some active
ingredients for crop protection products are prohibited over time
or the renewal of approval for use is refused.
12
In Hyundai Heavy
Industries Holdings/Daewoo Shipbuilding & Marine Engineering,
the Commission found that innovation was needed in the market
for large LNG carriers to reduce the boil-off rate of the
9
M.10188 Illumina/GRAIL, press release of 6 September 2022 available
at https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/ip_22_5364.
10
M.8788 Apple/Shazam, paragraph 163.
11
M.7932 Dow/DuPont, paragraph 1976 and M.8084 Bayer/Monsanto.
12
M.7932 Dow/DuPont, paragraph 1977.
transported LNG, to improve cost/effectiveness, and reduce fuel
consumption and CO
2
emissions.
13
Industries with a high level of IP protection. The level of
innovation effort in an industry can depend on the innovators’
ability to protect or appropriate their innovation results and
prevent knowledge spillovers to other firms. A firm will be less
likely to invest in innovation if its competitors could free-ride off
that investment by imitating. Wide-spread, efficient and lengthy
IP protection in an industry usually indicates a high level of
appropriability and the importance of innovation.
For instance, in Dow/DuPont, the Commission found that
appropriability in the crop protection industry was high pre-
merger. Most of the innovation takes place via the introduction of
new products (i.e., new active ingredients), which are patent
protected for a long time (25 years), while enjoying significant
sales with high margins both during the patent period and post-
patent expiry.
14
Similarly, in General Electric/Alstom, the
Commission noted the importance of intellectual property rights
and know-how in the market for heavy-duty gas turbines.
15
Therefore, in both cases, the Commission found innovation to be
an important parameter of competition and specifically assessed
the effects of the merger on innovation.
Industries with a high level of contestability. Markets or
industries where the best product wins shares away from rival
suppliers tend to incentivise innovation. When a firm knows it can
gain or protect profitable sales by providing greater value to
customers, it and its rivals will be motivated to innovate. If,
on the contrary, market shares are sticky, for example, because
consumers have strong brand preferences or high switching
costs, relatively few sales are contestable and innovation
incentives will be lower.
16
Process innovation. Innovation can also involve the
implementation of a new or significantly improved production or
delivery method. This includes significant changes in techniques,
equipment and/or software. Such process innovation may
decrease the unit costs of production or increase the quality of
products and delivery in many industries, including in mature
sectors. For instance, just-in-time production in car
manufacturing allowed to significantly reduce production costs by
reducing automakers’ working capital needs.
1.2 Quality and product differentiation
Quality often plays a central role in consumer decisions, and
therefore the competitive dynamics of markets. The term
“quality” can be defined as the range of product characteristics,
13
M.9343 Hyundai Heavy Industries Holdings/Daewoo Shipbuilding &
Marine Engineering, Section 8.3.3.
14
M.7932 Dow/Dupont, paragraph 458.
15
M.7278 General Electric/Alstom, paragraph 388.
16
C. Shapiro, “Competition and Innovation - Did Arrow Hit the Bull’s Eye?,
page 364.
Non-Price Competition: EU Merger Control Framework and Case Practice |
Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
4
other than price, which affect the value of the product to
consumers. These characteristics can include functionality,
design, know-how, track-record, durability, reliability, and
technology. Improving product characteristics covers both
providing a product of higher quality (i.e., vertical product
differentiation) and serving differentiated consumer tastes (i.e.,
horizontal differentiation).
In some differentiated product markets, firms may offer different
options of those characteristics, sometimes at different price
points. This is why customers across various industries may
attach a significant value to having access to high-quality
products at a competitive price. In this context, quality is one of
the most relevant non-price parameters of competition in
markets where product differentiation plays an important role
and/or where price competition is less relevant.
Industries with a (high) level of differentiation. The
importance of quality often depends on whether a market is
differentiated and whether quality is one of the top parameters
of competition. The Commission regularly reviews mergers in
differentiated markets and has found quality to be a
determinative parameter of competition. This is notably true in
the manufacturing industry, where industrial customers might
have specific requirements in relation to the characteristics,
reliability and durability of certain materials or parts.
The Commission’s practice in mergers between steel
manufacturers illustrates this trend, with the Commission’s focus
on quality as a prevailing parameter of competition being guided
by the existence of certain customers’ specific requirements or
the distinction, across the industry, of high-end v. low-end
products.
17
For example, in Tata Steel/thyssenkrupp/JV, the
Commission found that automotive customers had particularly
stringent requirements for hot-dip galvanised steel products used
for the exterior parts of a car, including the product’s technical
capabilities in terms of surface quality, which were one of the
most relevant parameters of competition.
Other examples abound. Thus, in markets for bespoke equipment
manufactured in response to particular technical requirements,
and set out in tender specifications by each individual customer,
quality is, by definition, a top parameter of competition and
determines the degree of closeness of competition.
18
In cases
involving food products, products may be geographically
differentiated, such that different levels of quality are attributed
or perceived, depending on a product’s origin.
19
The Commission
17
See cases M.8713 Tata Steel/thyssenkrupp/JV, paragraph 145 et seq.
and 798 et seq.
18
See for example M.9343 Hyundai Heavy Industries Holdings/Daewoo
Shipbuilding & Marine Engineering, paragraphs 105 and 396; M. 9779,
Alstom/Bombardier, paragraph 345 and 378.
19
See for example cases M.9110 Amerra/Mubadala/Nireus/Selonda,
paragraph 161, M.6850 Marine Harvest/Morpol, paragraphs 27-28,
M.10699 SalMar/NTS paragraphs 14-22, where the Commission
focused on quality as a declination of fish origin, an important
parameter of competition in the relevant market.
thus examines a variety of aspects of quality that may be
relevant depending on the industry at stake, with examples
ranging from interoperability across medical equipment,
20
to
network quality in mobile telecommunication services,
21
or to the
composition of a specific product in the food and chemical
industries.
22
Quality may also depend on the capacity of the
suppliers to adapt to specific consumers’ tastes.
23
Finally, the importance of quality in differentiated markets is also
manifest in situations where brands matter. In Merck/Sigma
Aldrich, the Commission thus found that quality (chemical
composition, purity of the product) was perceived by customers
through brands and worked as an important parameter of
competition, notably due to the strong safety hazard in the
laboratory chemicals markets.
24
Industries where price competition is less relevant. Quality
also plays an important role in the assessment of mergers in
markets where price competition is less relevant. In so-called
‘zero-price’ markets, competitors offer products and services for
free and thus, the impact of a merger on prices for customers
may not be the relevant metric for assessment. Instead, the
potentially negative effects of such transactions lie elsewhere
for instance, in the form of quality degradation.
This phenomenon can also be observed in mergers in the digital
sector that do not concern zero-price markets such as online
advertising, where quality is a relevant parameter of competition.
For example, in Google/Fitbit, the Commission considered that the
target’s data was bringing an additional advantage to Google’s
already dominant position in online advertising when competing
on non-price parameters such as quality with other players.
25
1.3 Data protection and privacy
Data is a key input into many online services. The use of data or
access to data plays an important role in the assessment of
20
M.9945 Siemens Healthineers/Varian Medical Systems, paragraph 116,
where the Commission found that simulators and radiotherapy
solutions were differentiated products and focused on interoperability
as a form of quality.
21
M.7018 Telefónica Deutschland/E-Plus, where the Commission found
that retail mobile telecommunication services was a differentiated
product and that the merging parties competed closely on the quality
of their networks.
22
See cases M.9019 Mars/AniCura, paragraph 90, where the Commission
found that quality - in terms of ingredients and quality controls - was
an important parameter of competition for veterinarians when
selecting dietetic pet food and M.6813 McCain Foods Group/Lutosa
Business, paragraphs 10 and 35 where the Commission found that
potato products can be either premium or non-premium quality, when
sold to the food service market, depending on frying time, different
coating, and yellow colour as well as content of dry solids which
impacts crispness.
23
See case M.10433 Vivendi/Lagardere where the Commission found that
the market for people magazines was a differentiated one on the basis
of the quality of the magazine, including the way in which the
information provided is treated.
24
M.7435 Merck/Sigma Aldrich, paragraph 136 and ff.
25
M.9660 Google/Fitbit, paragraph 452 and ff.
Non-Price Competition: EU Merger Control Framework and Case Practice |
Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
5
digital and tech mergers. In recent years, the Commission has
assessed data-related effects in several cases, as part of the
assessment of horizontal effects stemming from data
accumulation or in vertical assessments, where data is an
important input and could lead to foreclosure of rivals from an
important data input.
26
Furthermore, data protection and privacy are particularly relevant
parameters of competition in mergers in the digital and
technology industries, where companies use the data collected
from customers/users for commercial profit. As such, the data
that a company controls have in some industries become a key
driver of competition and a source of competitive advantage.
While the protection of data and privacy per se are specifically
regulated by data protection regulations,
27
in some cases privacy
can be an important element of quality of a product or service
offered and thus a parameter of competition between the
merging parties and their rivals and an element of differentiation.
The Commission may also examine whether data protection
regulations can pose certain limitations on the merging parties,
for instance with respect to combination of datasets or rules on
the collection, processing, storage and usage of personal data.
1.4 Sustainability
Merger control can play a role in supporting and complementing
the green transition in all sectors of the economy, such as
pharma, high technology, manufacturing, construction as well as
recycling markets. Indeed, a merger could undermine
sustainability goals by reducing investments in green technology.
As such, the environmental effects of a merger can be
assimilated to a specific form of innovation theory of harm.
Sustainability can also be a very important consumer preference,
for instance attached to goods produced locally or free of
pesticides. While the Commission will only intervene under the
EUMR to the extent that an impediment to competition induces
environmental harm,
28
there is a clear trend towards the growing
importance of sustainability-related aspects in the Commission’s
merger reviews.
29
Sustainability in merger control is not limited to a defined set of
industries. Companies across all industries strive to become more
sustainable, green, and environmentally friendly. However, in
order to take environmental considerations into account in
26
For more details on the Commission’s assessment of data in merger
investigations, see the Competition Policy Brief, Issue 02/2022 “Merger
Enforcement in Digital and Tech Markets: an Overview of the European
Commission’s Practice”, Section 1.3.
27
For instance, the EU’s General Data Protection Regulation (Regulation
(EU) 2016/679) or the Privacy and Electronic Communications Directive
(Directive 2002/58/EC, as amended).
28
See to this effect the reasoning included in M.8084 Bayer/Monsanto in
Section XIV: Non-Competition Concerns.
29
For more details on the Commission’s approach to sustainability in
merger control cases, see the Competition Merger Brief, Issue 02/2023
September.
merger reviews, sustainability needs to play a role in the
competition between companies active in the given market.
Industries where sustainable products reflect consumer
preferences. In industries where consumer preferences for
(more) sustainable products are a key driver of competition, such
preferences need to be taken into account. Such preferences can
stem from personal preferences, ethical norms, societal norms or
environmental policies and can be observed across various
industries. For instance, more stringent carbon-footprint
standards resulting from the Green Deal
30
are pushing car
manufacturers to source ‘greener’ aluminium, with a low carbon
footprint. Thus, the Commission’s review of two recent cases in
the aluminium industry, Norsk Hydro/Alumetal
31
and KPS Capital
Partners/Real Alloy Europe,
32
considered customers’ preferences
for recycled aluminium products and production of aluminium by
using renewable energy or recycling. Waste management is
another example of an industry where customers care about
sustainability in the form of recycling, as shown for instance by
Schwarz Group/Suez Waste Management Companies.
33
Sustainability is also a factor to be taken into account when
assessing transactions involving consumer goods, as consumers
may have strong preferences based on societal or ethical norms
or environmental standards.
34
Industries driven by sustainable objectives. In some
industries, companies compete to bring green(er) technologies,
products, or services on the market. Such innovations can be
driven by environmental policy initiatives such as the EU Green
Deal and the accompanying targets included in the ‘Fit for 55’
package.
35
In the EU, the European climate law regulation
imposes a legally binding target of cutting net greenhouse gas
emissions in the EU by at least 55% by 2030 compared to 1990
levels. Meeting that target to ensure a transition to climate
neutrality will require significant changes in business models and
product offering across industries, which will prompt businesses
to bring innovations to the market in order to stay competitive.
Greener energy sources, less polluting cars and planes, energy
efficient buildings, bio and organic food products, reusable
materials, cleaner cities are just a few of many examples of how
sustainability objectives will change (and are already changing)
market dynamics. For instance, emission-heavy industries such as
the construction industry and more specifically concrete
production need to adapt. Recently in Sika/MBCC,
36
the
30
For an overview of the EU Green Deal policy initiative, see for instance
https://commission.europa.eu/strategy-and-policy/priorities-2019-
2024/european-green-deal_en.
31
M.10658 Norsk Hydro/Alumetal.
32
M.10702 KPS Capital Partners/Real Alloy Europe.
33
M.10047 Schwarz Group/Suez Waste Management Companies.
34
See, for instance, case M.7220 Chiquita Brands International/Fyffes,
where the Commission found that customers made a clear distinction
between organic/Fairtrade and conventional bananas.
35
For an overview of the legislation included in the Fit for 55 package,
see the press release: Completion of key ‘Fit for 55' legislation
(europa.eu).
36
M.10560 Sika/MBCC.
Non-Price Competition: EU Merger Control Framework and Case Practice |
Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
6
Commission observed that the production of greener chemical
admixtures that can reduce CO
2
emissions were part of the
merging parties’ R&D efforts and a parameter of differentiation
for customers The Commission took this into account when
assessing the closeness of competition between the parties and
their competitors, as well as in the assessment of the remedy
proposal.
1.5 Capacity and reliability of supply
In markets where capacity cannot be expanded easily, the
existence of excess capacity, capacity constraints or planned
capacity expansions becomes an important non-price parameter
of competition. Many basic industries are characterised by a form
of price competition with capacity constraints because new plants
require significant capital investment and time. In these markets
capacity decisions become a variable of competition that
determine market power and dynamic outcomes. For example,
capacity was an important parameter of competition either for
market definition or for the competitive assessment in the
following industries: aluminium production Novelis/Aleris,
37
base
and process oils in Nynas/Shell/Harburg Refinery,
38
PVC supply in
INEOS/Solvay/JV,
39
crop protection in Dow/DuPont, beverage cans
in Ball/Rexam,
40
titanium dioxide pigments in Tronox/Cristal,
41
steel production in Tata Steel/thyssenkrupp/JV, and stainless steel
in Outokumpu/Inoxum.
42
However, capacity can also be an important parameter of
competition in network industries like aviation (Ryanair/Aer
Lingus
43
cases) where airports can be congested, and mobile
telecommunications (Hutchinson 3G UK/Telefónica UK
44
) where
capacities might be limited by long-term contracts.
2. Where and how to take non-price
competition into account?
When assessing a merger and its impact on competition, the
Commission takes into account non-price parameters of
competition and the non-price effects of a concentration in
different parts of its assessment, namely when defining markets
(2.1), assessing the competitive impact (2.2), and potential
efficiencies (2.3) of a merger, as well as when assessing the
suitability of remedies (2.4). This is also relevant when taking
jurisdiction over certain cases which fall below the notification
thresholds (2.5).
37
M.9076 Novelis/Aleris.
38
M.6360 Nynas/Shell/Harburg Refinery.
39
M.6905 INEOS/Solvay/JV.
40
M.7967 Ball/Rexam.
41
M.8451 Tronox/Cristal.
42
M.6471 Outokumpu/Inoxum.
43
M.4439 Ryanair/Aer Lingus, M.5434 Ryanair/Aer Lingus II, M.6663
Ryanair/Aer Lingus III.
44
M.7612 Hutchinson 3G UK/Telefónica UK.
2.1 Market definition
Non-price factors influence consumers’ preferences. Therefore,
such factors play a role in the assessment of substitutability and
whether products sold in certain geographic regions constitute
effective alternatives for customers, in other words whether the
conditions of competition (not only on price) are sufficiently
homogeneous in a given region. As such, the Commission
assesses not only price, but also non-price factors when
determining the exact scope of the product and geographic
market definition in merger cases.
Innovation spaces and areas. Innovation can play a role at
product market level as well as on an industry-wide level. The
level of innovation of a product can play a role when defining the
boundaries of a relevant market, for example by informing
demand and supply side substitutability.
In cases where effects on innovation are relevant, the potential
output of the relevant research and discovery activities is
typically several years away from commercialisation. The
definition of the relevant market may therefore be based on
specific innovation pipelines and pipeline products. This is
particularly true in the pharmaceutical industry where the
innovation activities and pipelines are often focused on specific
areas of treatment or modes of action. While such products are
not yet on the market, they have a pathway to commercialisation
and may constitute a basis to define the relevant market.
However, innovation activities do not always target specific,
existing, or future product markets, but may take place at an
earlier stage, before any product market is identified. In such
situations, while companies do compete in certain innovation
activities, these can be more properly defined as “innovation
areas” or “innovation spaces”. The merging parties’ overlaps in
innovation spaces may differ from their overlaps in product
markets and pipeline products.
45
In addition, the parties’
importance as innovators may be different from their position in
product markets. As a result, it may be necessary to identify and
examine the innovation spaces in which market players apply
their research efforts to determine the scope and significance of
innovation competition.
The Commission’s practice thus identified innovation spaces in
agrochemical mergers. In Dow/DuPont, the Commission analysed
innovation competition in the whole industry and in innovation
spaces consisting of groupings of crop/pest combinations at the
global or at least EEA-wide level to assess how agrochemical
companies compete to discover and develop new active
ingredients.
46
Similarly, in Bayer/Monsanto, the Commission
assessed innovation competition between both companies in a
number of innovation spaces, for example for traits, consisting of
45
According to paragraph 38 of the Horizontal Merger Guidelines,
assessing pipelines and pipeline products is only one example of how
to assess the effects of a merger on innovation.
46
M.7932 Dow/DuPont, paragraphs 362 and 361.
Non-Price Competition: EU Merger Control Framework and Case Practice |
Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
7
groupings of crop/functionality combinations as well as for crop
protection.
47
The concept of innovation spaces is relevant in other industries,
where innovation takes place at an early stage before a relevant
market can be identified. Such is the case, for instance, in certain
financial services. Thus, in Deutsche Börse/NYSE Euronext, the
Commission found that the merger between two major stock
exchanges would have limited the introduction of new products
and would have reduced innovation in technology, process, and
market design in relation to several types of European financial
derivatives. The Commission’s investigation focused on the
European innovation space for equity indices.
48
The Commission’s 2024 Market Definition Notice recognizes the
importance of innovation as a key parameter of competition
relevant for market definition. As innovative industries
characterised by significant R&D present specific characteristics
affecting competitive relationships, the Commission takes such
specificities into account, for instance with respect to pipeline
products and innovation efforts.
49
Relevant markets by quality standard. Quality can play an
important role at product or geographic market level and can
lead to the Commission identifying separate markets. The Market
Definition Notice relies on quality as one of the parameters of
competition that the Commission takes into account when
defining markets for instance, when assessing demand
substitution in product market definition, when analysing barriers
and costs associated with switching demand to potential
substitutes (e.g., due to uncertainty about the quality of
alternative products), or when defining markets in the presence
of discrimination between customers or customer groups by
offering different level of quality of products.
50
In its decisional
practice, the Commission has defined distinct markets based on
quality considerations in a wide variety of sectors. For example,
for hot dip galvanised steel products for the automotive
industry,
51
farmed seabream seabass of Turkish origin
52
and
premium frozen potato products.
53
Sustainability as a factor affecting substitutability. The
Commission takes into account customers’ sustainability
preferences when defining markets.
54
Sustainability-driven
customer preferences can determine the extent of demand-side
substitutability. Thus, for example, in Marine Harvest/Morpol,
customer preferences for sustainably farmed salmon were one of
the factors that led to the conclusion that farming and primary
47
M8084 Bayer/Monsanto, theory of harm outlined in paragraphs 80-88.
48
M.6166 Deutsche Börse/NYSE Euronext, paragraph 923.
49
Commission Notice on the definition of the relevant market for the
purposes of Union competition law (OJ C 1645, 22.02.2024), “Market
Definition Notice”.
50
Market Definition Notice, paragraphs 23, 27, 57, 88.
51
M.8713 Tata Steel/ThyssenKrupp/JV, paragraphs 145-259.
52
M.9110 Amerra/Mubadala/Nireus/Selonda, pargraph 68.
53
M.6813 McCain Foods Group/Lutosa Business, paragraph 35.
54
Market Definition Notice, paragraph 15.
processing of Scottish salmon is not part of the same market as
Norwegian salmon
55
In Novelis/Aleris,
56
the Commission
concluded that aluminium and steel for car body parts were not
part of the same market, particularly in view of CO
2
emission
reduction targets, that required fuel savings and that were driving
‘light weighting’ of vehicles (since lighter vehicles consume less
fuel) and thus demand by car manufacturers of aluminium ABS
(body sheets) of a high grade and performance. In another
aluminium case, Norsk Hydro/Alumetal,
57
the Commission found
that low carbon is at least an element of differentiation that
plays a role at product and geographic level when it comes to
solid advanced aluminium foundry alloys.
Sustainability also plays a role in the definition of the relevant
geographic market, as observed in Schwarz Group/Suez Waste
Management Companies. The investigation in that case showed
that Dutch customers tried to avoid transporting lightweight
packaging for sorting over long distances in order to minimise the
associated CO
2
emissions. The environmental cost of transport
was also a factor taken into account in tender procedures, where
more distant lightweight packaging sorting plants were penalized
in tenders due to the increased CO
2
emissions associated with
longer transport.
58
Ultimately, the relevant geographic market
was defined as national, i.e., the Netherlands.
Privacy and data protection. In some cases, where privacy is
an important consideration for consumers and a parameter of
competition between the merging parties, the Commission will
consider the level of privacy protection afforded when defining
product and geographic markets.
59
Such considerations are likely
to be particularly relevant in cases involving digital, technological,
or communication products and services, where consumers’ data
forms part of the product. One example of such products are
professional social networking sites. In Microsoft/LinkedIn, the
Commission considered privacy requirements and the data
protection regulatory framework in the geographic market
definition assessment. The Commission’s investigation
highlighted differences in the regulatory and privacy
requirements among EEA countries, which stakeholders viewed as
examples of differences when it comes to the provision of social
network services across the EEA. More specifically, with respect to
professional social networks, certain stakeholders considered
privacy considerations to play an important role as a requirement
demanded by local customers, as privacy rules vary among
jurisdictions.
60
55
M.6850 Marine Harvest/Morpol.
56
M.9076 Novelis/Aleris.
57
M.10658 Norsk Hydro/Alumetal, press release of 4 May 2023 available
at https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/ip_23_2566.
58
M.10047 Schwarz Group/Suez Waste Management Companies,
paragraphs 44, 56-58.
59
Market Definition Notice, paragraph 15.
60
M.8124 Microsoft/LinkedIn, paragraph 121.
Non-Price Competition: EU Merger Control Framework and Case Practice |
Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
8
2.2. Competitive assessment
In markets where companies offer differentiated products,
customers base their purchasing decisions on parameters that go
beyond the mere price of a given product. Whether it is the
innovativeness of products, the quality of products, product
choice or the ability to offer a good level of security of supply,
shorter lead-times or sustainable products, such non-price
elements have an impact on the way companies compete against
each other.
Therefore, when assessing whether a merger would harm
competition, the Commission carries out a holistic assessment of
the factors driving the competition between the parties and their
competitors. Non-price parameters of competition have therefore
played a role in the assessment of closeness of competition and
barriers to entry and expansion. Moreover, the Commission has
developed a case practice on how to review horizontal as well as
non-horizontal mergers that would lead to loss, reduction and/or
harm to innovation, quality, and capacity.
Closeness of Competition
Closeness of competition between companies is determined not
only by comparing the prices of their products, but also by
assessing the non-price competition between them. Thus, while
non-price factors may not always justify a definition of a
narrower product or geographic market, the Commission takes
these factors into account in its competitive assessment and in
particular in the assessment of closeness of competition between
the merging parties and vis-à-vis their competitors.
Innovation rivalry between merging parties. Closeness in
innovation can manifest itself through competitive overlaps
within each R&D stage (e.g., overlapping discovery targets/lines of
research, overlapping pipelines in the discovery stage, and
overlapping pipelines in the development stage), and across
different stages of the lifetime of a product (e.g., discovery
pipelines-to-development pipelines, overlaps, discovery pipelines-
to existing product overlaps, and development pipelines-to-
existing product overlaps). The existence of such overlaps
between the merging parties indicates that absent the merger
the merging parties expected to divert future sales from each
other by innovating.
While lines of research or pipelines at the discovery stages have
an uncertain outcome, such inherent uncertainty should not be
confused with whether or not competition concerns are present.
Even in the presence of uncertainty as to the outcome of the
innovation process, a merger between firms with competing lines
of research is likely to affect the incentives to invest in research,
leading to either delay, reorientation, or discontinuation of lines
of research or pipelines and ultimately the chance of an
innovation outcome.
61
Quality. Quality can play an important role as both a parameter
of differentiation and of competition when assessing closeness
of competition between the merging parties and their
competitors. A merger between two quality-leaders, i.e.,
companies offering products or services of a particularly high
quality, might result in market power going beyond what is
indicated by the parties’ market shares. As a result of a merger,
these firms could profitably raise prices precisely because of the
quality-related divide that will separate them from competitors
or possible entrants, without necessarily reducing quality. In prior
cases, the Commission thus found that a merger of companies
with a particularly good quality record in industries where quality
was of great importance to customers would have resulted in
higher prices.
62
Conversely, a merger between companies offering products of
inferior quality may also result in market power going beyond
what is indicated by the parties’ market shares, especially vis-à-
vis certain customer groups. For example, in Telefónica
Deutschland/E-Plus the Commission argued that the merging
parties were close competitors because their networks were
perceived of being of lower quality than the networks of
Deutsche Telekom and Vodafone [i.e., the only other two
operators of an own mobile network in Germany] and concluded
that the parties were close competitors for mobile products that
offer a network quality below the level achieved by the networks
of Deutsche Telekom and Vodafone”. The Commission thus found
that because of the perceived lower network quality, Telefónica
and E-Plus would compete for the same subset of customers that
do not place as high a value on network quality.
63
Merging parties’ efforts to bring more sustainable
products to the market. As demand for more sustainable and
environmentally-friendly products grows, companies face
pressure to meet that customer and societal demand, which can
be observed in the companies’ innovation efforts as well as
potential M&A strategies. Differences in sustainable product
positioning and related R&D capabilities influence how closely
companies compete with each other. Sustainability is therefore a
parameter of differentiation when assessing closeness of
61
For example, in Dow/DuPont, the Commission found that both parties
were competing head-to-head for a significant number of innovation
spaces in herbicides, insecticides, and fungicides with specific and
similar discovery targets and past innovations. This analysis was based
on the parties’ internal documents and their patents. See case M.7932
Dow/DuPont, paragraphs 1123 1245.
62
For example, in M.9343 Hyundai Heavy Industries/Daewoo Shipbuilding
& Marine Engineering for large LNG carriers; in M. 8900
Wieland/Aurubis Rolled Products/Schwermetall for rolled copper
products; and in M.7435 Merck/Sigma Aldrich for catalogue solvents
and inorganics.
63
M.7018 Telefónica Deutschland/E-Plus, paragraphs 292-293.
Non-Price Competition: EU Merger Control Framework and Case Practice |
Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
9
competition between the merging parties and their competitors.
64
For instance, the Commission can assess how closely the parties’
products compete based on the products’ emission levels.
65
If
parties are strong innovators, the Commission also assesses their
green R&D capabilities and technological advancements, notably
when the investigation shows that green innovation is a key
challenge in the industry going forward.
66
Moreover, customers’
sustainability preferences, for instance, in terms of environmental
costs can also be relevant for the assessment of the merging
parties’ geographic closeness.
67
Important competitive force
Some firms may have more of an influence than that which their
market share would suggest.
68
Their capacity to disrupt the
market may not only result from their (aggressive) pricing
strategy but also relate to other competitive dynamics, such as
innovation, or quality.
Innovation. Innovation capabilities are of course a critical
parameter of competition which is not (yet) reflected in (actual)
sales or turnover. Hence, an innovative player would typically be
considered as an important competitive force, having more
influence than reflected in its market shares.
69
This has also been
reflected in the Commission’s case practice. To give one example,
in Dow/Dupont, the Commission considered that by removing two
out of three main R&D integrated players, the transaction would
remove an important competitive force.
64
See, for example, M.8829 Total Produce/Dole Food Company,
paragraphs 81, 91.
65
In General Electric/Alstom, the Commission concluded that the merger
would have eliminated a significant and close competitor of GE in the
overall market for 50Hz heavy-duty gas turbines, given that GE and
Siemens had developed machines which are relatively close to Alstom's
machines in terms of emissions. See M.7278 General Electric/Alstom,
paragraphs 511 and ff.
66
In Sika/MBCC, the Commission found that innovation efforts and R&D
capabilities to develop new polymers and bring more sustainable
chemical admixture formulations to the market played a key role in the
concrete/cement industry. Sika and MBCC were both strong innovators,
including on green R&D, which was seen as important to meet
sustainability challenges. The parties’ innovation capabilities were one
of the main factors taken into account by the Commission when
assessing the closeness of competition between them and vis-à-vis
other players. See M.10560 Sika/MBCC, paragraphs 210-226. In
Hyundai Heavy Industries/Daewoo Shipbuilding & Marine Engineering,
the Commission found that the parties were each other’s close
competitors on a number of key parameters of competition such as
innovation and that both parties were important innovators in vessel
technologies including those technologies allowing for lower fuel
consumption and lower emissions. See M.9343 Hyundai Heavy
Industries/Daewoo Shipbuilding & Marine Engineering, paragraphs 400
and ff, 491 and ff.
67
In Schwarz Group/Suez Waste Management Companies, sorting plants
for lightweight packaging waste (LWP) located further away from
collection points imply more CO
2
emissions and therefore higher long-
term environmental costs. Therefore, the parties were considered to
compete closely with one another for Dutch LWP sorting contracts
while sorting plants located in Germany were competing less closely.
See M.10047 Schwarz Group/Suez Waste Management Companies,
paragraph 118.
68
Horizontal Mergers Guidelines, paragraph 37.
69
Horizontal Mergers Guidelines, paragraph 38.
Quality. Quality can play an important role in the assessment of
whether one of the merging parties is an important competitive
force and may grow going forward. For example, in Hutchison 3G
UK/Telefónica UK, the Commission found that Three, was an
important competitive force, not only due to its aggressive device
prices but also in light of its generous data offers and attractive
voice/text bundles.
70
This approach was confirmed by the CJEU,
finding that price is often not the only important parameter for
assessing competitive dynamics, in particular in differentiated
product markets in which quality and innovation could play a key
role in the positioning of the products concerned. Therefore, an
exclusively price-focused approach for the purposes of classifying
an undertaking as an ‘important competitive force’ would
necessarily be incomplete.
71
Sustainability. A company offering greener products may also
be considered as an important competitive force, especially if the
sector and customers’ preferences are becoming more sensitive
to environmental aspects. In this context, the company might be
expected to grow in the near future, and its market share would
not reflect its full competitive potential. This consideration has
been assessed in the Commission’s past cases.
72
Barriers to entry and expansion
Higher barriers to entry or expansion are likely to result in fewer
successful entrants in a market or industry. Non price elements,
such as innovation and capacity, often constitute significant
barriers to entry or expansion due to the significant costs and
time associated with those intermediary processes.
Innovation. Industries with high levels of innovation are often
characterised by high barriers to entry as well. Innovation-
intensive industries, markets, or products require significant
expertise, know-how and financial investments. For example, in
Pfizer/Hospira, the Commission found that higher concentration
levels could dampen innovation for the discovery and
development of certain biosimilars due to high barriers to entry.
Biosimilars are biologic medical products which exhibit high
molecular complexity and may be quite sensitive to changes in
manufacturing processes. The Commission found that barriers to
entry for biosimilars are typically higher than for generics and the
pool of potential entrants upon patent expiry is typically smaller
for biological drugs than for small-molecule chemical drugs.
73
Mergers can thus increase innovation-related barriers to entry or
expansion, for example if a rival is partially foreclosed and
70
M.7612 Hutchinson 3G UK/Telefónica UK, paragraph 764 and ff.
71
CJEU, judgement of 13 July 2023, Case376/20 P, paragraph 165.
72
For example, in Norsk Hydro/Alumetal, the Commission concluded that
given the sustainability trend, automotive customers may increasingly
turn to recycled aluminium providers such as Alumetal in the future, so
that the latter may be an important competitive force. However, on
balance, and considering the capabilities of other suppliers, the
Commission ultimately concluded that it would likely not be the case.
73
M.7559 Pfizer/Hospira, paragraph 54.
Non-Price Competition: EU Merger Control Framework and Case Practice |
Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
10
cannot reach the necessary scale to continue investing in
innovation.
Sustainability. In industries undergoing a green transition due
to customer demand or the need to meet various sustainability
goals and new environmental standards, sustainability can
represent a barrier to entry and expansion for market players.
This may be due to high capex investments needed to become
active on a certain market, the need to obtain regulatory permits
and meet, often demanding, regulatory requirements.
74
Innovation loss theories of harm
Economic literature suggests that less competition typically
reduces market-wide innovation, in particular in concentrated
markets. Specifically, the vast majority of ex post evaluations of
horizontal mergers estimate large negative effects on
innovations inputs and outputs.
75
The literature on patent races in the presence of uncertainty
supports the view that a reduction in rivalry in the process of
introducing innovation can be expected to lead to less innovation,
and thereby to consumer harm. For example, economic models
indicate that a reduction in the number of firms racing to be the
first to patent a new product leads to a delay in the expected
arrival date of a new invention.
76
In addition to these general observations, there are a number of
criteria or factors which can indicate that a transaction would
have a particularly strong effect on innovation activities and
product innovation. The Horizontal Merger Guidelines specify that
if a merger combines two important innovators, or eliminates a
firm with promising pipeline products, the transaction can
eliminate an important competitive force and thus lead to a
significant impediment of effective competition against which the
Commission should intervene.
77
The innovation potential of the
merging firms is taken into account regardless of the current
market position of the companies.
78
Instead, the Commission has
in its case practice relied on several forward-looking criteria.
R&D ‘input. The R&D investments of a company as well as the
headcount and capabilities of its R&D function especially in
74
In KPS Capital Partners/Real Alloy Europe, the market investigation
showed that there were high barriers for entry and expansion for a
company to become active and maintain presence in dross recycling
and slag recycling, in particular due to the capex investment needed,
the need to obtain an operating permit, as well as national
requirements regarding waste treatment and air pollution. See
M.10702 KPS Capital Partners/Real Alloy Europe, paragraphs 183
187 and 217 219. Similarly, in Hyundai Heavy Industries/Daewoo
Shipbuilding & Marine Engineering, the Commission assessed how
certain innovative vessel technologies including those allowing for
lower fuel consumption and lower emissions could represent barriers to
entry or expansion. See M.9343 Hyundai Heavy Industries/Daewoo
Shipbuilding & Marine Engineering, paragraphs 1052 and ff.
75
Haucap/Stiebale, Non-price Effects of Mergers and Acquisitions
(2023), Section 2.1, paper commissioned by the European Commission.
76
See M.7932 Dow/DuPont, paragraph 48 for sources.
77
Paragraph 38 Horizontal Merger Guidelines.
78
See paragraphs 38 and 20b Horizontal Merger Guidelines.
comparison to its competitors can provide useful insights into a
company’s innovation strength and importance. For example, in
GE/Alstom, the Commission found that Alstom’s innovation
output was understated by its market shares. Its R&D spent,
headcount and testing infrastructure were proportionately greater
than its market share. Alstom’s large installed base also helped it
to develop and introduce a range of improvements and
modifications to its products.
R&D output. The number of patents, product launches and
pipeline projects can also provide an indication of a company’s
innovative strength. Such quantitative factors should be
complemented by a qualitative assessment. For instance, in
Dow/DuPont, the commission carried out a comprehensive
assessment of the parties R&D ‘output’. First, the Commission
found that both companies had ambitious targets for innovation
efforts and output (number of new products and innovative
impact in terms of new mode of actions, chemical classes, and
favourable regulatory profile). Second, the Commission calculated
the patent shares of Dow, DuPont and their competitors. This
calculation was based on the number of patents adjusted by their
quality. Such adjustment is important as patents can have very
different qualities. The quality of each patent was measured by
the number of citations accumulated in subsequent patents.
79
Third, the Commission assessed the firms’ capabilities to develop
and distribute active ingredients on a large scale in the market
based on their past commercial performance.
Killer acquisitions. Specific evidence of discontinuation of R&D
efforts by the merging parties may play a role in the
investigation of the effects of a merger. Such evidence can, for
example, relate to the closure of plants, the reduction of
innovation targets, or a cut in R&D budgets or investments.
Incumbent firms may acquire innovative targets solely to
discontinue the target’s innovation projects and pre-empt future
competition. For example, pharmaceutical industry data shows
that acquired drug projects are less likely to be developed when
they overlap with the acquirer’s existing product portfolio,
especially when the acquirer’s market power is large because of
weak competition or distant patent expiration.
80
Reactions of competitors. The competitive role played by non-
merging parties also needs to be assessed before concluding on
the significance of any loss of innovation competition from the
merger. If only a few non-merging parties effectively constrain
the merging parties, then it is more likely that the merger will
lead to a significant loss of innovation competition. Moreover, in a
concentrated market, any reaction of non-merging parties to the
loss of innovation competition between the merging parties is
unlikely to fully offset the reduction in innovation, in particular
when competitors innovative capabilities differ from those of
the merging parties.
79
M.7932 Dow/DuPont, paragraph 387.
80
Cunningham/Ederer/Ma, Killer Acquisitions, Journal of Political
Economy, Volume 129, Number 3, March 2021.
Non-Price Competition: EU Merger Control Framework and Case Practice |
Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
11
Previous or historic developments. Past events can provide a
useful indicator for assessing the relationship between increased
concentration levels and innovation in a certain industry or
market. In Dow/DuPont for example, the Commission observed
that previous waves of consolidation were accompanied by a
certain reduction in the innovation intensity and output, as
demonstrated by lower R&D spend and fewer active ingredients
for pesticide products brought to the market.
81
Overlaps in pipeline products. When assessing the effects of
a merger on innovation the Commission may look at the merging
parties’ and their competitors’ pipeline products. Such
assessment is of particular relevance in the research-intensive
pharmaceutical industry with its clear and often standardised
development and regulatory approval processes. In
J&J/Actelion
82
, the Commission thus found that both companies
were developing a promising drug with a similar new mode of
action to treat insomnia. Both drugs were at an early stage of
clinical trials (so-called Phase II), but close in their expected
efficacy and safety profiles. In Novartis/GSK’s oncology
business
83
, the Commission found that both companies had R&D
programmes for innovative drugs aimed at treating skin and
ovarian cancer with the same mechanism of action. In
Pfizer/Hospira, the Commission found that Pfizer was developing
a competing medicine to Hospira’s biosimilar for the treatment of
chronic inflammatory diseases. In all three cases, the
Commission’s concern was that the merged entity would have
fewer incentives to continue the overlapping or duplicate research
programmes, not only for cost reasons but also in light of a
heightened risk of future cannibalisation.
Non-horizontal effects. Innovation concerns can also arise in
non-horizontal mergers, where the parties’ activities are vertically
linked or complementary to each other. In particular, foreclosure
risks can manifest themselves in a reduction of innovation
activity. Recently, in Illumina/GRAIL, the Commission found that
customer foreclosure strategies could have stifled innovation on
the emerging downstream markets for NGS-based cancer
detection tests. According to the Commission’s in-depth
investigation, following the acquisition of GRAIL, Illumina would
have had the ability and incentive to foreclose GRAIL’s
competitors from its high-throughput NGS systems. It could for
instance refuse to supply its NGS systems to GRAIL's rivals,
increase the prices, or degrade quality and delay supplies. This
could have had severe and negative effects on the innovative
capabilities of early cancer detection test developers and of this
emerging industry as a whole at a very critical stage of
development.
84
In another case, Broadcom/Brocade, the
Commission assessed the innovation impacts of a potential
interoperability degradation between networking products
(upstream) for communications and datacentre infrastructures
81
M.7932 Dow/DuPont, paragraphs 2124 - 2158.
82
M.8401 J&J/Actelion.
83
M.7275 Novartis/GSK’s oncology business.
84
M.10188 Illumina/GRAIL.
and applications (downstream).
85
The risk that merging parties
might implement interoperability degradation strategies and
thus negatively impact innovation is higher in fast-developing
and fast-growing industries, in particular those driven by
technology and data.
Dynamic effects. Foreclosure cases in dynamic industries are
often about preventing future innovation. A dominant firm in one
market may foreclose a rival in a neighbouring market,
preventing it from becoming an innovative force that competes
better in the neighbouring market or that would innovate into the
market where the dominant firm is already active.
86
Both
Broadcom/Brocade and Illumina/GRAIL concerned dynamic
industries and the Commission was concerned that foreclosure
strategies could lead to a reduction of future competition on the
respective downstream markets.
Quality degradation
A merger can result in a degradation of quality and product
variety. The results of empirical studies indicate that merger-
induced market power increases tend to reduce incentives to
provide high-quality products.
87
Merging firms might also have an
incentive to drop competing varieties within the newly combined
firm to avoid cannibalisation and save fixed costs. The effects of
a merger on quality tend to be very industry-specific and the
Commission found that a merger would result in a degradation of
quality in a number of cases, for example concerning the quality
of food,
88
of medias content,
89
of medical devices
90
and of mobile
communication networks.
91
Data driven theories of harm
Privacy as a competitive parameter and element of
quality. In cases where privacy and data protection play a role in
the competitive dynamics, the Commission assesses the extent to
which the parties compete with respect to privacy and whether
the transaction could have a negative impact on privacy-related
competition. For instance, in Apple/Shazam, privacy was
considered an important element of competition between music
streaming service providers. The Commission assessed how the
companies treated user data and their relevant data collection
practices/transmission of personal data.
92
In Microsoft/LinkedIn,
the market investigation confirmed that privacy was an important
parameter of competition and a driver of customer choice in the
85
M.8314 Broadcom/Brocade, paragraph 205.
86
For more details on the Commission’s assessment of dynamic effects
in merger investigations, see the Competition Policy Brief, Issue
02/2022 “Merger Enforcement in Digital and Tech Markets: an Overview
of the European Commission’s Practice.
87
See e.g. Haucap/Stiebale, Non-price Effects of Mergers and
Acquisitions (2023), page 32, paper commissioned by the European
Commission.
88
M.9019 Mars/AniCura, paragraph 125.
89
M.10433 Vivendi/Lagardere, paragraphs 1910 and ff.
90
M.9945 Siemens Healthineers/Varian Medical Systems, paragraph 108.
91
M.7612 Hutchinson 3G UK/Telefónica UK, paragraph 2308 and ff.
92
M.8788 Apple/Shazam, paragraphs 313 315.
Non-Price Competition: EU Merger Control Framework and Case Practice |
Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
12
market for professional social networking services.
93
The
Commission took this factor into account when assessing the
impact of foreclosure concerns if a competitor which offers a
greater degree of privacy protection to users than LinkedIn were
to be marginalized (or entry of any such competitor would be
made more difficult as a result of the merger), the transaction
would also restrict consumer choice in relation to this important
parameter of competition.
94
Similarly, in Facebook/WhatsApp,
privacy and security were considered as important parameters of
competition in relation to consumer communication services, and
an element of differentiation between the parties’ offering.
95
These cases illustrate that in sectors where data, and in
particular personal data, is a source of value, the privacy
protection offered by companies to that data is an important
competitive parameter. The potential impact of the transaction
on this parameter of competition is therefore not overlooked.
Using customer data to put competitors at a
disadvantage. When assessing mergers involving companies
that collect customer data, it is also important to look at the
potential use of that data post-transaction as the merged entity
could have the ability and incentive to use such data and
information to put competitors at a disadvantage. For example, in
Apple/Shazam, the Commission assessed whether, through the
acquisition of control of the Shazam app and Shazam database,
Apple could gain access to certain data on its competitors. The
Commission considered that the customer information to which
Apple would gain access constituted commercially sensitive
information. When assessing whether Apple would have the
ability and incentive to use the customer information to put
competitors at a disadvantage, the Commission took into
consideration the legal obligations imposed on Apple by the
relevant privacy and data protection regulations.
96
Combination of datasets. In some cases, limitations posed by
data protection rules can restrict or prevent certain data-related
actions by the parties, such as combination of datasets. If the
Commission finds that the applicable rules do not pose such
limitations, the Commission examines the competitive effects
stemming from such combination of datasets. For instance, in
Microsoft/LinkedIn, the Commission concluded that the data
protection rules that Microsoft and LinkedIn were subject to,
limited their ability to process the dataset they maintain.
97
Capacity-related theories of harm
The immediate effect of any merger is a reallocation of
production capacities, which can lead to price effects if rivals
face capacity constraints.
98
Moreover, as regards non-price
93
M.8124 Microsoft/LinkedIn, footnote 330.
94
M.8124 Microsoft/LinkedIn, paragraph 350.
95
M.7217 Facebook/WhatsApp, paragraphs 87, 102 and footnote 79.
96
M.8788 Apple/Shazam, paragraphs 209 259.
97
M.8124 Microsoft/LinkedIn, paragraphs 177, 178.
98
For example, in M.8451 Tronox/Cristal, the Commission found that the
ability of existing suppliers to increase production in response to a price
competition, e.g., where capacity expansion is a variable of
competition, a merger can have dynamic effects on capacities
should it change the merged company’s incentives to expand
capacity and rivals’ reaction to it.
Merging producers may compete less aggressively on capacity
expansions post-transaction, as they will take account of the
negative effect that new capacity in the market has on the sales
of the respective merging partner. Stated differently, pre-
transaction each merging party only took into account the
negative impact that new capacity would have on its own sales
(via the decrease in overall market price due to the additional
capacity) but did not take into account the negative effect on the
sales of the other merging party. This effect is internalised post
transaction, which results in a loss of competition on the market.
The merger might not only change the future capacity extensions,
or lead to a plant closure and a reduction in capacity, but also
change the geographic distribution of capacity if competition has
a strong local aspect.
Dynamic competition in capacities was an important element in
the Commission’s decisional practice. For example, in
Novelis/Aleris, the Commission concluded that the transaction
would have dynamic effects in the medium/long term, because
Novelis’ limited incentive to increase overall market capacity
would be further weakened. The decision argued both that post-
transaction Novelis would have less incentive to increase capacity
than an independent Aleris, and that Novelis would have fewer
incentives to implement its own expansion plans. The
investigation analysed in detail the past capacity expansions in
the market, as well as the future expansion plans of Novelis and
Aleris. In Ball/Rexam, the investigation focused similarly on future
capacity expansions. Absent the transaction, it was likely that
Rexam would have increased capacity in North-East Europe and
consequently reduced market concentration. This future capacity
expansion of Rexam was a key factor in determining the size and
geographical distribution of the commitments. In
INEOS/Solvay/JV, the history of output and capacity reductions
provided evidence on the likely effects of the merger. Earlier
mergers of INEOS were followed by output reductions in North-
West-Europe and increased exports, and finally plant closures
that reduced the effective capacity of the merged entity. These
capacity reductions likely lead to increased market power, since
the decision also found that margins in North-West-Europe
increased compared to the rest of Europe after the second
previous merger.
Whether these theories of harm apply in a concrete case depends
both on the level of the parties’ capacity shares and the extent of
spare capacities held by rivals. All else being equal, anti-
competitive effects are more likely if merging parties control a
large part of the available capacity after the transaction and
rivals have little excess capacity.
increase by the merging Parties is limited by the low levels of spare
capacity and competitors' existing commitments to other customers.
Non-Price Competition: EU Merger Control Framework and Case Practice |
Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
13
Finally, capacity constraints can often be local, especially in the
case of products of basic industries that require costly
transportation. The result is geographic product differentiation
that sometimes makes detailed assessment of local competition
necessary. For example, in Ball/Rexam, a case involving beverage
cans, the Commission’s assessment focused on customers and
their potential suppliers: capacity-based market shares for
catchment areas around customers with filling locations were the
basic tools of the competitive assessment. Based on an
assumption about the feasible transport distance, the
Commission was able to assess which potential suppliers and
with what capacity could serve customers in a given geographic
area.
99
2.3 Efficiencies
In addition to negative non-price effects, the Commission
recognises that mergers may also result in non-price benefits to
consumers, such as bringing new and improved products. Such
positive effects are typically assessed by the Commission in the
context of efficiency claims. To be accepted, the claimed
efficiencies have to benefit consumers, be merger specific and be
verifiable. Under the Horizontal Merger Guidelines, efficiencies
should, in principle occur within the markets where competition
concerns are found.
Innovation efficiencies. Mergers may in some circumstances
enhance innovation, for example by allowing the parties to share
knowledge more effectively and by internalising knowledge spill
overs. The Horizontal Merger Guidelines specifically mention "new
or improved products or service resulting from efficiency gains in
the sphere of R&D and innovation".
100
In its review of agrochemical mergers (Dow/DuPont and
Bayer/Monsanto), the parties did not provide evidence of case-
specific innovation efficiencies. The Commission observed that in
the relevant innovation spaces the protection against imitation
was strong already pre-merger, thanks to effective IP rights and
product lifecycle management techniques. Hence, it was less
likely that each of the two mergers would increase the incentive
to innovate by internalising significant involuntary knowledge
spillovers.
Quality efficiencies. In several mobile telecom mergers, the
parties argued that their transaction would result in quality
improvements, such as larger networks, better coverage and
faster roll-out of the newest-generation mobile network with
better quality and higher data speeds. In Orange/MásMóvil, the
Commission considered that network roll-out efficiencies could
be accepted in principle, if they are incremental to the roll-out
plans absent the merger. If accepted, these efficiencies would
have to be weighed against the anti-competitive harm of the
merger in terms of the share of consumers benefiting from
99
M.7567 Ball/Rexam, Sections 9.2.1 and 9.2.2.
100
Horizontal Merger Guidelines, paragraph 81.
higher network quality and consumers’ willingness to pay for
higher quality. However, in line with earlier cases, the Commission
found that these improvements were subject to an uncertain
timeline, not verifiable and not merger-specific because the
Parties would have realistic alternatives to expand capacity on a
stand-alone basis or enter into network-sharing agreements as a
less anti-competitive alternative to the merger.
101
Green efficiencies. A merger may have positive effects on
sustainability, for instance by improving product quality, by
decreasing the level of toxicity of a product or by enabling cost
reductions resulting from generating less waste or requiring the
use of fewer raw materials. Efficiencies can also result in the
development of newer technologies, novel “green” products and
more generally “green” innovations. For example, in
Aurubis/Metallo, a case that concerned access to copper scrap in
the EEA, the Commission looked at positive technological
synergies associated with the transaction, in particular improved
combined metal extraction capabilities and know-how of the
merged entity, the benefits of which could in part be passed on to
suppliers of the merged entity.
102
2.4 Remedies
Remedies should eliminate the competition concerns identified by
the Commission entirely. To do so, the Commission accepts
proposals that resolve the issues on a lasting basis, and this is
why structural divestments of activities as a going concern to
suitable buyers are the preferred option.
103
Given the importance
of non-price competition, the Commission makes sure that all
relevant assets are included in the divestment, in particular R&D
and pipeline projects, so that it will continue its activities and
development as envisaged absent the merger. The Commission
therefore must ensure that the buyer will have the ability and
incentives to continue investing in ongoing projects. Non-price
competition, including digitalisation, also raises certain theories
of harm related to interoperability and data for which non-
structural remedies exceptionally may appear as equally
effective as
104
- and potentially more appropriate than - a
divestment, with the objective to open markets on a lasting basis.
R&D and pipeline projects. When divesting a business, the
assets should comprise on-going pipelines or R&D projects. The
commitments generally specify that all know-how, patents, IP,
materials, data, documentation and proprietary information be
101
Cases M.10896 Orange/MásMóvil, M.6497 Hutchison 3G
Austria/Orange Austria; M. 6992 Hutchison 3G UK/Telefónica Ireland;
M.7018 Telefónica Deutschland/E-Plus; M.7612 Hutchison 3G
UK/Telefónica UK.
102
M.9409 Aurubis/Metallo, paragraphs 831 and ff. See also the
Competition Merger Brief, Issue 02/2023 September, which provides
more details on the Commission’s assessment of the efficiencies
submitted in M.9409 Aurubis/Metallo.
103
Commission Notice on Remedies, paragraphs 10 and 15.
104
Commission Notice on Remedies, paragraphs 17 and 61.
Non-Price Competition: EU Merger Control Framework and Case Practice |
Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
14
included.
105
To ensure that the purchaser will have the ability and
financial incentives to pursue the ongoing projects, the
Commission ensures that the divestment will be supported by
sufficient expertise including by requiring the purchaser to be
already active in the sector
106
-, as well as sufficient staff via
possible secondment of personnel or new hires as needed and
funds.
107
The commitments may also foresee a temporary
obligation from the merged entity to provide transitional support
to the purchaser.
108
Importantly, considering that R&D and
pipelines are typically developed at global level, the
commitments may need to include the global R&D organisation,
either because the theories of harm relate to global R&D
markets, as was the case in Dow/Dupont, or because global R&D
is necessary to ensure the viability and competitiveness of the
divestment business going forward. Thus, in Sika/MBCC, while the
relevant problematic markets for the supply of chemical
admixtures were national in scope, the divestment of MBCC’s
business included all global R&D assets, sites, personnel, IP, and
other relevant assets to fully address the Commission’s concerns
in the EEA, and make sure the divestment business would
continue developing innovation contributing to reducing CO
2
emissions.
In cases where products are co-developed, the commitments may
also consist in giving more rights to the partner.
109
On the other
hand, commitments falling short of a transfer such as providing
only licenses on R&D and pipeline projects to the remedy taker
are typically rejected considering that competition will not be
preserved on a lasting basis.
110
By allowing the preservation of innovation competition, merger
remedies may even have positive effects beyond what the
divestment business had planned to develop and invest in absent
the merger. For example, in General Electric/Alstom, the remedy
constituted of a divestiture of the main, technologically most
advanced parts of Alstom’s heavy duty gas turbines business,
including pipeline technology. The remedy package thus equipped
105
See for example in the pharmaceutical industry, M.7746 -
Teva/Allergan Generics; and M.7559 Pfizer/Hospira; and M.7917
Boehringer Ingelheim/Sanofi animal health business.
106
See for example M.10506 - Parker/Meggitt where the purchaser
needed to be an existing manufacturer of aerospace components; and
M.10560 Sika/MBCC where the purchaser needed to demonstrate its
proven incentive to continue investing in the R&D activities of the
Divestment Business globally.
107
See for example on staff, M.10506 - Parker/Meggitt, and M.11043 -
Novozymes/Chr Hansen Holding, and on financing, M.8401
J&J/Actelion. See also commitments foreseeing a CAPEX escrow
account to be funded by the merged entity to make sure the envisaged
investment projects including into plants will be continued by the
buyer, for example M.10702 KPS Capital Partners/Real Alloy Europe.
108
See for example. M.7559 Pfizer/Hospira.
109
In Novartis/GSK Oncology Business, the Commission accepted the
remedies proposed by the parties, whereby Novartis committed to fully
return one of the treatments where the Commission raised competition
concerns to its owner and licensor Array BioPharma Inc. (Array) and to
divest the other treatment of concern to Array. See also for example
M.8401 J&J/Actelion whereby J&J granted new rights to its partner
Minerva over the global development of a pipeline product.
110
See for example M.10188 Illumina/GRAIL.
the remedy taker to successfully finalise the development of
Alstom’s highly efficient gas turbines. Moreover, using its know-
how and capabilities, Ansaldo (the remedy taker) was in fact able
to go even further in innovating those turbines by using hydrogen
as a fuel, which can significantly decrease CO
2
emissions. Thus,
the remedy package in the hands of a suitable purchaser led to
positive effects on the environment by ensuring continued
innovation in energy efficient electricity generation.
Access and interoperability. When mergers raise non-
horizontal competition issues related to degradation of
interoperability or access to data, the Commission accepted in the
past, exceptionally, non-structural remedies. The objective is to
ensure that the markets will remain open and competitive in the
long run, and that the ability and incentives of competitors to
develop their products and compete effectively are preserved.
While the assessment is very case specific, certain factors are
typically relevant to decide whether non-structural remedies
would be appropriate in a specific case, including that (i) the likely
problematic conducts are well-identified, (ii) the number of
access or interoperability seekers is reasonable and (iii) standard
terms of access or interoperability can be defined. In previous
cases, the merged entity committed to make or continue
making - its product interoperable with competitors’ products.
For example, in Siemens Healthineers/Varian Medical Systems,
Siemens committed to adhere to industry-wide interoperability
standards and make its medical imaging and radiotherapy
solutions compatible with rivals radiotherapy and imaging
solutions, including by providing the relevant information and
technical assistance to third parties and customers. In other
cases, the merged entity committed to make or continue
making - certain data available to competitors. For example, in
Google/Fitbit, Google committed to maintain access to users’
health and fitness data to software applications, and to continue
licensing public web Application Programming Interfaces (APIs) to
ensure that wrist-worn devices will interoperate with Android
smartphones.
111
More recently in BroadCom/VMWare, BroadCom
committed to ensure interoperability of competitors’ products
with its server virtualisation software, and provide competitors
access to relevant information, including the source code.
112
To consider those remedies suitable in specific cases, the
Commission also needs to conclude that there are effective
monitoring mechanisms. In the past, the Commission did not
accept non-structural remedies considering that they were not
removing the competitive concerns entirely, especially as they
could not be properly and effectively monitored. Recently, in
Illumina/Grail, the Commission rejected the proposed
111
Google also committed not to use the users’ health and fitness data
collected from wrist-worn wearable devices via sensors for Google Ads
(search ads, display ads, ads intermediation) and to maintain technical
separation. The data will be stored in a “data silo” which will be
separate from any other dataset maintained by Google and available
for advertising.
112
See also M.10262 - Meta/Kustomer.
Non-Price Competition: EU Merger Control Framework and Case Practice |
Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
15
commitment by Illumina to give access to rivals to its next-
generation sequencing systems as (i) they did not effectively
address all the possible foreclosure strategies that Illumina could
engage in; (ii) it would have been easy for Illumina to circumvent
its obligations and grant preferential treatment to GRAIL, and (iii)
it would have been difficult to monitor them due to their
complexity and the fact that GRAIL's rivals would hardly have
been able to detect breaches.
2.5 Suitability of referrals
The Commission recently evaluated the effectiveness of its
turnover-based jurisdictional thresholds, considering that the
sales generated by a company may not fully reflect its
competitive potential.
113
This is typically the case due to non-
price competition, with high-value digital or biotech companies
being acquired by large firms even if they generate little to no
turnover (yet). Following this evaluation process, the Commission
concluded that this “jurisdictional gap” could be addressed
effectively by inviting Member States to refer potentially
problematic cases falling below national or EU notification
thresholds to the Commission, using the powers under Article 22
of the EUMR.
114
As per the Commission’s guidance,
115
EU Member
States are able to refer to the Commission acquisitions or merger
cases below EU or national thresholds when the turnover of at
least one of the undertakings concerned does not reflect its
actual or future competitive potential.
116
As a consequence, non-price elements such as innovation or data
play a decisive role in the assessment on whether a merger case
is a suitable candidate for a referral. By way of examples, a
referral would be appropriate in cases where the undertaking at
issue is (i) a start-up or recent entrant with significant
competitive potential that has yet to develop or implement a
business model generating significant revenues (or is still in the
initial phase of implementing such business model); (ii) is an
important innovator or is conducting potentially important
research; (iii) is an actual or potential important competitive force
or (iv) has access to competitively significant assets (such as for
instance data or intellectual property rights).
113
Commission Staff Working Document, Evaluation of procedural and
jurisdictional aspects of EU merger control; 26 March 2021.
114
This approach was endorsed by the General Court in T-227/21,
Illumina v Commission.
115
Commission Guidance on the application of the referral mechanism
set out in Article 22 of the Merger Regulation to certain categories of
cases, paragraph 19.
116
Commission Guidance on the application of the referral mechanism
set out in Article 22 of the Merger Regulation to certain categories of
cases, paragraph 19.
In two of the three referrals which the Commission accepted
under its revised approach to Article 22 EUMR to date, innovation
aspects played an important role. In Illumina/GRAIL, the
Commission accepted the referral request because of concerns
that the transaction could result in a discontinuation of the
access to Illumina’s products for GRAIL’s competitors and thus
impede the innovation efforts of GRAIL’s rivals. The other referral
case, Qualcomm/Autotalks,
117
concerns the development of
vehicles-to-everything communication (V2X) technology, which is
key to improving road safety, traffic management and reducing
CO
2
emissions as well as for the deployment of autonomous
vehicles.
Conclusion
In pursuit of its goal, preventing competitive harm to consumers,
the Commission uses several competition parameters in
assessing mergers. While price will continue to play a pivotal role,
other parameters of competition have played an increasingly
important role in recent years, such as quality, innovation, data
protection and privacy. Among the newer developments is
sustainability.
All these parameters of competition can play a decisive role at
every stage of the Commission’s decision-making process, from
market definition to the competitive assessment., efficiency
claims and remedies.
In its assessment, the Commission applies its consumer welfare
standard approach, which includes intervention in cases which
would otherwise do harm to the competitive process, covering all
parameters of competition, in order to contribute to a strong and
vibrant European economy, to the EU consumers’ benefit.
The Commission continues refining its assessment and is keen to
ensure that consumers are not denied non-price benefits of
competition in reflection of market changes and realities.
117
M.11212 Qualcomm/Autotalks, see European Commission, Daily News
18 August 2023 (accessible via
https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/mex_23_4201).
The content of this article does not necessarily reflect the
official position of the European Commission. Responsibility
for the information and views expressed lies entirely with
the authors.
Competition Policy Brief
Assessing Innovation Competition in
Pharma Mergers
Vasiliki Dolka, Susanna Kärkelä, Aiste Slezeviciute, Zsolt Vertessy
Introduction
The review of mergers and acquisitions in the pharmaceutical
industry is a high-stakes endeavour presenting unique challenges.
Merger control ensures that consolidation does not lead to higher
prices for patients and health systems. In parallel, competition
agencies must also assess the impact on innovation.
1
This
assessment is crucial so that pharma companies continue to be
incentivised to tackle public health challenges by researching,
developing, and commercialising promising new products. Not
only are there persisting unmet medical needs, but the nature of
threats to health also changes due to the emergence of new
diseases (such as Covid-19), as well as a reduction in the efficacy
of existing products, for instance through antimicrobial
resistance. Innovation is key to tackling evolving and unmet
medical threats.
The commercial reward for successful innovation in the
pharmaceutical sector is a de facto monopoly through the patent
system. This results in high rewards during the period of
protection which can bear a direct relationship to M&A strategies
in the sector. Large pharmaceutical companies facing the
expiration of the main patents covering their blockbuster drugs in
the coming years may turn to acquisitions of promising pipelines
still benefitting from patent protection to help safeguard their
future growth.
2
Other companies have amassed major cash
1
The benefits of innovation for competition are discussed in detail in the
Commission’s Competition Policy Brief of April 2016, available at
https://op.europa.eu/en/publication-detail/-/publication/764b96c6-9a82-
11e6-9bca-01aa75ed71a1/language-en/format-PDF/source-
195709315.
2
Patent expiries are being estimated to result in a 46% decline in
revenues for the 10 largest global pharmaceutical companies by 2030.
For instance, 2023 saw the end of exclusivity in the US for AbbVie’s
Humira, the best-selling drug worldwide with global revenues of USD
21 billion in 2022. AbbVie’s CEO indicated in early 2023 that investors
should “expect us to act” on M&A opportunities if the right one should
arise (AbbVie Q4 2022 Earnings Call). This has played out with its
(proposed) acquisitions of Immunogen (USD 10 billion), Cerevel (USD
8.7 billion). Likewise, Merck is also preparing for the expiry in 2028 of
patents for Keytruda, which accounted for more than a third of its
sales in 2022, by acquiring other promising treatments to strengthen
its product pipeline
reserves during the
pandemic which can now
be used to fuel M&A.
3
These acquisitions may
result in the purchaser
entering new markets but
may also result in
competitive overlaps
between the purchaser and
the target with products at
the same or different
stages of the product
lifecycle. Any competitive
assessment needs to be
tailored taking these
dynamics into account.
In this context, the
Commission continues to
apply merger control rules
vigorously and rigorously in
the pharmaceutical sector
to ensure that innovation
and competition on the
merits is preserved, and in
turn preserving choice and
quality at competitive
prices. This Brief aims to
summarise the key
developments and recent
experiences in the
European Commission's extensive practice of reviewing
pharmaceutical mergers, with a focus on innovation.
This Brief will firstly summarise the Commission's well-
established framework for defining markets in pharmaceutical
cases. A vast range of different treatments may target the same
disease while being highly differentiated. Thus, the task of
establishing the boundaries of the market can be complex, but
nevertheless remains an essential one to ensure that the merger
(https://www.economist.com/business/2023/04/20/big-pharmas-patent-
cliff-is-fast-approaching).
3
Pfizer’s sales of its Covid vaccines drove it to record a record revenue
of USD 100.3 billion in 2022, while engaging in a number of high-
profile acquisitions during 2022-23 (inter alia, it acquired Global Blood
Therapeutics for USD 4.7 billion, Biohaven for USD 11 billion and
Seagen for USD 43 billion).
Assessing Innovation Competition in Pharma Mergers | Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
17
review can capture the dynamics of the market. The
pharmaceutical sector is highly regulated, including pricing and
reimbursement schemes at national level, which drives a
delineation of relevant geographic markets for marketed drugs
along national borders, while at the innovation or development
stage competition is often far wider, potentially at least EEA-
wide, or global.
In the second and third sections, this Brief will focus on the
substantive assessment of horizontal and non-horizontal effects
in pharmaceutical mergers with particular focus on their impact
on innovation. Given the high risk / high reward nature of
pharmaceutical research and development (“R&D”) and the
transparency regarding pharmaceutical pipeline products years
before they reach the market,
4
a transaction’s rationale may give
important insights into the parties’ expectations regarding their
future potential and the development of the competitive
landscape. A “big pharma” company buying a start-up may grant
the target the financial and operational capability to effectively
bring a product to market, with pro-competitive effect. However,
this ability to identify the new drugs’ characteristics, prospects
and target market also means that, in some cases, there is a risk
that the impact of the deal could be less positive. In the presence
of horizontal overlaps, the transaction could result in a
concentration of market power in the purchaser’s hands by
combining competing marketed (or soon-to-be marketed)
products, leading to higher prices or reduced quality. Alternatively,
the result of the acquisition could be that the purchaser
discontinues its own or the target’s R&D efforts, which can lead
to price increases or reduced choice. Indeed, academic studies
have suggested that some pharmaceutical companies may use
early-stage acquisitions as a way to ‘kill’ potential competitive
threats that may emerge in future.
5
Even if the target does not
compete with the purchaser in the same market, non-horizontal
concerns may arise: the combination of the merging parties may
enable the merged entity to foreclose rivals and capture a
greater market share once its product reaches the market.
Given the high stakes for patients and health systems, it is
imperative that competition concerns be resolved in a way that
ensures a competitive market structure on a lasting basis. In view
of this, the Commission's remedies policy in pharmaceutical
mergers is outlined in the fourth section.
The fifth section summarises the recent evolution of the
Commission's approach to jurisdiction. An unusual feature of
4
In the pharmaceutical industry, pipeline drugs go through several
development stages, starting with preclinical trials in laboratories on
animals, and later moving on to clinical trials on humans. Clinical trials
in humans (so called “Phase I”, “Phase II” and “Phase III” clinical trials,
see further footnote 16) are strictly regulated to ensure the protection
of trial subjects and the reliability of the results. The results of these
trials are published.
5
See, for example, Cunningham, C., Ederer, F. and Ma, Song, Killer
Acquisitions, J. of Political Econ., (Mar. 2021), vol. 129, no. 3: 649702.
The Commission has commissioned an ex post evaluation to assess the
prevalence of killer acquisitions in the pharmaceutical industry and
determine what are the key features of such killer acquisitions this
study is in progress. The risk that M&A can result in the discontinuation
of pipelines is also identified in European Commission, Directorate-
General for Research and Innovation, Pang, T., Folwell, B., Osborne, A. et
al., Study on the impact of mergers and acquisitions on innovation in
the pharmaceutical sector, Publications Office of the European Union,
2020, https://data.europa.eu/doi/10.2777/323819.
pharmaceutical transactions is the lengthy development process
for medicines on average, it takes 12-15 years from discovery
to bring a drug to market.
6
However, the promise and potential of
new medicines is at times clear at an early stage in this process,
meaning that even years before a product has been launched, a
start-up can be valued in the billions. The potential competitive
impact is therefore reflected in a target’s valuation by the
purchaser but not in its revenues, which is the metric used for the
notification thresholds set out in the EU Merger Regulation
(“EUMR”). This fifth section outlines the Commission's recalibrated
approach to referrals pursuant to Article 22 of the EUMR, which
enables it, in cooperation with EU Member States, to ensure that
transactions involving low-turnover but highly innovative targets
do not escape review.
Finally, in the sixth section, this Brief highlights the importance of
international cooperation and dialogue. Given that blockbuster
medicines are developed and commercialised at global scale,
competition agencies should ensure a consistent and coherent
approach to examining pharmaceutical mergers. Notably, the
sixth section outlines the recent conclusions of the inter-agency
working group between the Commission and the Canadian, UK
and US competition authorities.
1. Market definition
Whilst market definition in pharmaceutical mergers for marketed
drugs follows a well-established framework, the assessment of
innovation elements is more complicated because the precise
features of pipeline products may not yet be realised.
For commercialised products, in line with the Market Definition
Notice,
7
the Commission assesses substitutability from the
demand and supply sides. The general starting point for
pharmaceutical products is the Anatomical Therapeutic Chemical
(ATC) Classification System devised by the European
Pharmaceutical Market Research Association (“EphMRA”).
8
From
this starting point, the Commission assesses further whether it is
appropriate to distinguish between over-the-counter (“OTC”) and
prescription (“Rx”) medicines, indication denoted by the ATC 3
level,
9
the mode of action (such as topical or systemic), the mode
of delivery (such as oral or injectable) and, where relevant, the
6
OECD, Pharmaceutical Innovation and Access to Medicines (2018).
7
Commission Notice on the definition of the relevant market for the
purposes of Union competition law (OJ C 1645, 22.02.2024), “Market
Definition Notice”.
8
The ATC system is a hierarchical and coded four-level system which
classifies medicinal products by class according to their indication,
therapeutic use, composition, and mode of action. In the first and
broadest level (ATC 1), medicinal products are divided into the 16
anatomical main groups. The second level (ATC 2) is either a
pharmacological or therapeutic group. The third level (ATC 3) further
groups medicinal products by their specific therapeutic indications.
Finally, the ATC 4 level is the most detailed one (not available for all
ATC 3) and refers for instance to the mode of action (e.g. distinction of
some ATC 3 classes into topical and systemic depending on their way
of action) or any other subdivision of the group. Medicinal products are
classified according to the ATC system in the IMS Midas data base.
9
For OTC-sold drugs, the Commission may also use the Consumer
Health Classification (“CHC”, administered by IQVIA, an American
multinational company serving the combined industries of health
information technology and clinical research), which is equivalent to
ATC. See, e.g., Commission decision of 22 October 2021 in Case
M.10247 CVC/Cooper.
Assessing Innovation Competition in Pharma Mergers | Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
18
line of treatment.
10
This assessment is informed by the views
expressed by so-called “key opinions leaders” in the medical field,
submissions from the merging parties and other evidence on the
file, such as the parties’ internal documents.
However, these elements are less likely to be known when a
merger assessment is required either for pipeline products or for
new or nascent markets. For pipeline products, the further the
development cycle of a product is advanced, the more can be
known about the product’s features and the more certain the
assessment can be about market definition. For example, the ATC
3 code and mode of action will normally be clear from the outset
of clinical trials but only by Phase III or later will the line of
treatment be known. In this case, the market definition cannot
assess whether a segmentation of that market by line of
treatment would be relevant. Earlier in the development cycle, it
may not be known for which applications the pipeline product
may succeed, and in turn whether it will replace or compete with
any existing products or create new demand.
The assessment of market definition is more complicated when it
comes to products in development that do not fall within the
established ‘pipeline’ assessment, but rather concern innovation
and development in entirely new or nascent markets.
For example, in the recent Illumina/GRAIL
11
case, the Commission
found that GRAIL and its rivals were engaged in an innovation
race to develop and commercialise early cancer detection tests.
The Commission concluded that while there was still uncertainty
about the exact results of this innovation race and the future
shape of the market for early cancer detection tests, protecting
current innovation competition was crucial to ensure that early
cancer detection tests with different features and price points
would come to the market. As such, the product market definition
assessment focused on the innovation race. The relevant
question in defining the market in such cases is whether there is
a meaningful competition between the companies engaged in
R&D at the development stage of the product. Such competition
may take place for funding or resources, and is evidenced by the
product’s ‘race towards commercialisation’ (for example
evidenced by various ‘prelaunch activities’, such as regulatory
filings, clinical trials, engagement with the health care systems,
etc.). The exact nature of the product and parameters of
competition at the commercialisation stage may not yet be
determined at the development stage. As such, product market
definition at the development and commercialisation stages
differs.
In terms of geographic scope, medical products are generally sold
in accordance with the national regulatory and reimbursement
regimes and the relevant markets are deemed national in scope.
Innovation markets on the other hand are generally found to be
wider than national and may be at least EEA-wide or even global.
In past decisions, the Commission found that, when innovating in
drug pipelines and medical devices, companies tend to track their
10
Line of treatment refers to the setting for which a specific drug is
indicated. For example, a drug indicated for second-line treatment
should be used only after another therapy (the first-line treatment) has
proven ineffective or if this other therapy cannot be prescribed to a
specific patient.
11
Case M.10188 Illumina/GRAIL. See press release:
https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/IP_22_5364.
competition globally or EEA-wide and may compete on a
worldwide basis for funding opportunities and talent.
12
2. Horizontal mergers: assessment of
innovation competition
The Horizontal Merger Guidelines
13
recognize “the effect on
innovation” as one of the elements to be assessed, equating the
potential competitive harm that may be caused by a reduction of
innovation with price increases and reduction of output, choice or
quality of goods and services. The Horizontal Merger Guidelines
specify that a merger between important innovators, for instance
between two companies with pipeline products related to a
specific product market can eliminate an important competitive
force and thus lead to a significant impediment to effective
competition.
14
Given that the pharmaceutical sector is driven by
innovation, it has always been important to identify and intervene
against pharmaceutical mergers that have the potential to
compromise R&D efforts and hamper the launch of innovative
new products. The Commission applies a four-layer competitive
assessment framework,
15
with the aim of ensuring that all
potential effects of pharmaceutical mergers, and especially
innovation effects, are carefully scrutinised.
The first layer takes into account actual competition, assessing
the overlaps between the parties’ existing marketed products. The
second layer considers potential competition assessing the
overlaps between: (i) the parties’ existing marketed and pipeline
products at advanced stages of development; and (ii) the parties’
pipeline products at advanced stages of development.
16
17
The
12
For example, M.9461 AbbVie/Allergan, Commission decision of 10
January 2020, paragraph 13. M.9294 BMS/Celgene, Commission
decision of 29 July 2019, paragraph 8.
13
Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers under the Council
Regulation on the control of concentrations between undertakings,
Official Journal C 31, 5.2.2004. p. 5-18.
14
Horizontal Merger Guidelines, para. 38.
15
This framework was first introduced in cases involving the agricultural
sector (M.7932 Dow/Du Pont, Commission decision of 27 March 2017;
M.8084 Bayer/Monsanto, Commission decision of 21 March 2018),
before being applied to the pharmaceutical sector too (e.g. in M.7275
Novartis/GSK Oncology, Commission decision of 28 January 2015;
M.9294 BMS/Celgene, Commission decision of 29 July 2019 as well as
in M.8084 Bayer/Monsanto, Commission decision of 21 March 2018
and M.7932 Dow/Dupont, Commission decision of 27 March 2017).
16
The phases of clinical development for pipeline products can be
described as follows. Phase I starts with the initial administration of a
new drug into humans, with trials carried out on a small number of
people. The focus of Phase I trials is to confirm that the drug is safe to
use in humans and to identify the appropriate dosage and exposure-
response relationship. Phase II usually starts with the initiation of
studies to explore therapeutic efficacy in patients. Studies in Phase II
are typically conducted on a small group of patients that are selected
based on stricter criteria for indications. Phase III trials aim to
demonstrate or confirm therapeutic benefit in a larger group of
patients (Phase III trials will typically have hundreds of patients and
may have over a thousand, for example for autoimmune diseases).
Studies in Phase III are designed to confirm the preliminary evidence
accumulated in Phase II that a drug is safe and effective for use in the
intended indication and recipient population. Phase IV begins after drug
approval to monitor possible adverse reactions and/or new side effects
over time.
Assessing Innovation Competition in Pharma Mergers | Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
19
third layer consists of an analysis of innovation competition in
relation to the parties’ ongoing pipeline products, assessing the
risk of significant loss of innovation competition resulting from
the discontinuation, delay or redirection of the overlapping
pipelines (including early stage pipelines). The fourth layer takes
into account innovation competition in relation to the capability to
innovate in certain innovation spaces, assessing the risk of a
significant loss of innovation competition resulting from a
structural reduction in the overall level of innovation.
Innovation competition involving late-stage
pipelines
Overlaps involving late-stage pipelines (in Phase III clinical trials
or later), are assessed under the second layer of the
Commission’s framework. This involves investigating the overlap
between one party’s advanced pipeline(s) with the other party’s
existing or advanced pipeline product(s) (“pipeline-to-marketed”
and “pipeline-to-pipeline” overlaps, respectively). At this late
stage of development, it is usually possible to identify the
specific product market within which these pipeline drugs will
compete. The assessment of such cases takes into account the
effects on potential competition by considering: (i) the potential
adverse effects on future prices that may occur even if the
merged entity would bring all of the potentially competing
pipeline products to market; and (ii) the likelihood of
discontinuation of a pipeline product that could lead to the
reduction of product choice and higher future prices.
This approach can be seen more recently in the cases of
Abbvie/Allergan
18
and Takeda/Shire,
19
both concerning biologic
medicines
20
for inflammatory bowel disease. In Takeda/Shire, the
Commission assessed the pipeline-to-marketed overlap between
Takeda’s leading biologic treatment for IBD, which was the only
product available in the EEA at the time, and Shire’s pipeline
biological product for the treatment of IBD, which was expected
to launch prior to the patent expiry of Takeda’s product. The
Commission focused its analysis on the potential loss of
innovation and future competition in case Takeda were to stop
developing Shire’s new treatment post-Transaction, ultimately
finding that Takeda would be unlikely to continue developing
Shire’s new IBD treatment, as it would compete closely with
Takeda’s biologic treatment for IBD. Similarly, when assessing a
pipeline-to-pipeline overlap in Abbvie/Allergan, the Commission
found that brazikumab, a treatment for IBD that Allergan was
developing was likely to compete closely with a product Abbvie
was developing (risankizumab), as both products had the same
mode of action and line of treatment and were in the late stages
of development. The Commission thus found that AbbVie would
17
For pharmaceutical products, the Commission in principle considers
programmes in Phase III clinical trials as being at an advanced stage of
development.
18
M.9461 AbbVie/Allergan, Commission decision of 10 January 2020.
19
M.8955 Takeda/Shire, Commission decision of 20 November 2018.
20
Biologics refer to any type of medical therapy that is derived from
living organisms such as humans, animals, or microorganisms.
be likely to discontinue the development of Allergan’s pipeline
product post-transaction. The Commission’s investigation
revealed that the merger would likely lead to a loss of innovation
for the relevant treatments, as both products were part of a
promising class of biologics for which only two other competing
pipeline products existed. The transaction would likely have had
the effect of preventing a promising drug from reaching the
market, which could have led to the reduction of choice on the
market, and price increases for patients and healthcare systems.
Innovation competition involving early-stage
pipelines
The third layer involves evaluating the competitive effects of
transactions involving pipeline products in the early stages of
development.
21
In AstraZeneca/Alexion Pharmaceuticals,
22
the
Commission conducted a comprehensive competitive analysis of
horizontal overlaps between the parties’ pipeline drugs for the
treatment of lupus nephritis, follicular lymphoma, and peripheral
T-cell lymphoma, many of which were in Phase I and early Phase
II clinical trials. It concluded that no competition concerns were
likely to arise because the parties’ pipeline products were
expected to be sufficiently differentiated such that effective
competition would remain in the market post-transaction.
Similarly, in BMS/Celgene,
23
the Commission considered the
horizontal overlap between Celgene’s already marketed drug
Otezla and BMS’ pipeline treatments, one in Phase III and one in
Phase I clinical trials for the treatment of severe psoriasis and
psoriasis arthritis. Prompted by concerns from competitors, the
Commission went even further to assess an overlap involving a
drug in preclinical stage (in which Celgene had a financial option)
with a Phase III pipeline held by BMS. The Commission carefully
considered whether the parties’ pipeline products (as well as
products in preclinical stages i.e. before human clinical trials)
could replace existing treatments or generate new demand and
concluded that the merged entity would have no incentive to
disrupt the development of BMS’s pipeline treatments especially
because the parties’ drugs were sufficiently differentiated.
While in this case the Commission undertook a very thorough
analysis of the potential competitive constraints between BMS’
Phase III pipeline and Celgene’s preclinical stage programme
because of the concerns raised in the market investigation, in
most cases potential competitive constraints exerted by drugs in
preclinical stages are only exceptionally assessed. This is because
at a very early stage the indication and therapeutic use of the
pipeline may still be undetermined, and it may be difficult to
predict the competitive interaction between the various drugs.
21
M.7275 Novartis/GSK Oncology, Commission decision of 28 January
2018, where the Commission assessed for the first time all phases of
clinical research being carried out, including those concerning drugs in
early stages of development.
22
M.10165 AstraZeneca/Alexion Pharmaceuticals, Commission decision of
5 July 2021.
23
M.9294 BMS/Celgene, Commission decision of 29 July 2019.
Assessing Innovation Competition in Pharma Mergers | Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
20
Both cases affirm the importance of analysing innovation
competition and simultaneously reveal the underlying difficulties
of evaluating early-stage pipelines, as often the exact profiles
and prospects of these drugs remain speculative due to their
early stage of development and the limited availability of data.
Innovation spaces
With the fourth and final layer of assessment, the Commission
broadens the analytical scope by introducing the notion of
competition over innovation spaces.
24
,
25
This assessment goes
beyond examining specific potential products; it considers early
stage R&D efforts in relation to ideas or products which are
undefined or are years away from reaching the market.
26
In each
innovation space the Commission assesses overlaps between the
merging parties’ lines of research (encompassing the set of
scientists, patents, assets and equipment which are dedicated to
a given discovery target) and early and late stage pipeline
products.
27
This assessment usually takes into account the
parties’ and their competitors’ general innovation capabilities
beyond the competitive situation of specific marketed and
pipeline products. The Commission seeks to avoid a reduction in
innovation competition, for example if the merger results in there
being: (i) less competitive pressure between the players
remaining in the market, which therefore have a reduced
incentive to invest in or prioritise R&D; or (ii) the merged entity’s
innovation capabilities attaining such a size and strength that its
rivals could no longer effectively compete.
This framework of assessment has been applied in animal
healthcare and pharmaceuticals cases. In Elanco Animal
Health/Bayer Animal Health Division,
28
which concerned
pharmaceutical products for pets and livestock, the Commission
considered whether the transaction could lead to a reduction in
competition in certain innovation spaces but concluded that the
transaction would not result in a significant reduction in
innovation competition, as the parties were not considered to be
particularly strong innovators in the animal health space,
especially in comparison to their competitors.
29
In
AstraZeneca/Alexion Pharmaceuticals,
30
the Commission
considered that the transaction was unlikely to raise competition
concerns in this respect because the parties were not active in
24
For instance, in M.7932 Dow/Dupont, Commission decision of 27 March
2017, the Commission found that the transaction would be likely to
significantly impede effective competition as regards innovation both
in innovation spaces where the parties’ lines of research and early
pipeline products were overlapping and overall in innovation in the crop
protection industry. In order to conduct this assessment, the
Commission looked at the parties’ lines of research and early pipeline
products.
25
M.8084 Bayer/Monsanto, Commission decision of 21 March 2018,
footnote 23. As the Commission has explained R&D players do not
innovate for all the product markets composing a sector at the same
time, but tend to target specific spaces within that sector (“discovery
targets”).
26
M.7932 Dow/Dupont, Commission decision of 27 March 2017; M.8084
Bayer/Monsanto, Commission decision of 21 March 2018.
27
M.8084 Bayer/Monsanto, Commission decision of 21 March 2018.
28
M.9554 Elanco Animal Health/Bayer Animal Health Division,
Commission decision of 8 June 2020.
29
M.9554 Elanco Animal Health/Bayer Animal Health Division,
Commission decision of 8 June 2020, paragraphs 315-321.
30
M.10165 AstraZeneca/Alexion Pharmaceuticals, Commission decision of
5 July 2021, footnote 15.
the same R&D spaces, as Alexion’s R&D mainly focused on rare
diseases, which were outside the scope of the main drug portfolio
of AstraZeneca.
31
In Pfizer/Seagen,
32
the Commission found that
the transaction would not lead to a loss of innovation in the field
of oncology in general and in antibody drug conjugates (“ADCs”)
in particular,
33
given that a significant number of players
engaged in R&D activities would remain in the market.
3. Non-horizontal mergers: assessment
of innovation effects
Non-horizontal pharmaceutical mergers may raise competitive
concerns from the viewpoint of innovation by creating the ability
and incentive for the merged entity to engage in foreclosure
strategies that hinder innovation post-transaction. For instance,
the vertical link could enable the acquirer to profitably foreclose
competitors’ access to an important input, thereby reducing their
ability to develop a new downstream product.
This was the case in Illumina/GRAIL,
34
which the Commission
blocked for innovation-related vertical competition concerns. The
Commission concluded that the acquisition of GRAIL, a
development company that uses Illumina’s next generation
sequencing (“NGS”) systems to develop its innovative and
promising cancer detection tests, would enable and incentivise
Illumina, the unrivalled supplier of NGS systems, to engage in
foreclosure strategies against GRAIL’s rivals with a consequence
of hindering the development and commercialisation of early
cancer detection tests to the detriment of competition in the
internal market. As Illumina’s NGS technology was found to be a
“must-have” input on which GRAIL and its rivals depended, the
transaction would have allowed Illumina to cut GRAIL's rivals
access to the technology, or to increase prices, degrade quality or
delay supplies of its systems. These actions would have allowed
GRAIL’s product to reach the market first, thereby boosting its
competitive position to the detriment of its rivals.
Although Illumina would benefit from its anticompetitive
behaviour only at a later stage following the commercialisation
of GRAIL’s cancer detection tests, the Commission found that the
significant market potential and the ongoing innovation race in
the development and commercialisation of early cancer detection
tests gave Illumina an incentive to foreclose already at the time
of the transaction. In the absence of suitable remedies to ensure
that early cancer detection tests with different features and price
31
See also similar analysis in M.9294 BMS/Celgene, Commission decision
of 29 July 2019, footnote 28.
32
M.11177 Pfizer/Seagen, Commission decision of 19 October 2023 (not
yet published).
33
ADCs are a class of biopharmaceutical drugs designed as a targeted
therapy for treating cancer. They are made up of a monoclonal
antibody chemically linked to a cytotoxic agent (the payload), enabling
the payload to target specific cancer cells whose receptors or proteins
bind with that antibody.
34
M.10188 Illumina/GRAIL, Commission decision of 6 September 2022
(not yet published). While this case is not strictly in the pharmaceutical
sector, rather relating to medical devices and diagnostic tools, the
assessment is nevertheless of interest in the pharmaceutical context
too.
Assessing Innovation Competition in Pharma Mergers | Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
21
points would come to the market, the Commission prohibited the
transaction.
35
4. Remedies
The Commission’s remedies practice in the pharmaceutical sector
follows the principles of the Commission Remedies Notice. The
Notice specifies that structural commitments, such as the
divestment of a self-standing business unit, are typically
preferable to meet the objective of preventing a significant
impediment to effective competition by eliminating the concerns
entirely in a comprehensive and effective manner.
36
Nevertheless, non-structural remedies may be appropriate in
specific cases, provided they achieve this objective, are capable
of effective implementation and monitoring, and are not so
extensive and complex that it cannot be determined with the
requisite degree of certainty that they will be fully implemented
and are likely to maintain effective competition.
37
Regardless of
the type of remedy, its suitability must be examined on a case-
by-case basis, having regard to the structure and characteristics
of the market to assess whether they meet the basic aim of
ensuring a competitive market structure post-transaction.
In the Commission’s practice, structural remedies have been the
most common means to prevent problematic pharmaceutical
mergers from giving rise to a significant impediment to effective
competition. Since 2015, all conditional clearance decisions of
pharmaceutical transactions have involved a structural
component (whether a divestment or other arrangement to
terminate structural or licensing links), and in the vast majority of
cases a divestment of existing or pipeline pharmaceuticals was
the only commitment necessary to remove the concerns.
38
This
reflects the fact that divestitures are the best way to eliminate
concerns.
39
The fundamental importance of innovation in the pharmaceutical
industry is a key aspect that influences the Commission’s
remedies practice. In several cases, the commitment accepted
was not the divestment of an existing business generating sales,
but rather of a drug development pipeline. For example, having
found that Allergan’s IBD treatment in development was likely to
compete closely with AbbVie’s marketed treatment for IBD (see
further the paragraphs under the heading “Innovation competition
involving late-stage pipelines above), the Commission’s
35
Appeal pending at the EU General Court under Case T-709/22 Illumina
v Commission.
36
See Commission notice on remedies acceptable under Council
Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 and under Commission Regulation (EC)
No 802/2004, (2008/C 267/01) “Commission Remedies Notice”),
paragraphs 10, 15 and 17.
37
Commission Remedies Notice, paragraphs 13-14.
38
Beyond the pharmaceutical sector, the Commission’s interventions in
healthcare related mergers have involved non-divestiture remedies,
such as in the field of medical imaging (M.9945 Siemens
Healthineers/Varian Medical Systems, Commission decision of 19
February 2021) or dental equipment (M.7822 Dentsply/Sirona,
Commission Decision of 25 February 2016).
39
Commission Remedies Notice, paragraph 17.
clearance was conditioned on the divestment of the global rights
to develop, manufacture and market Allergan’s pipeline product.
40
However, development cycles for innovative drugs are long, risky
and require substantial investment before pipeline products are
brought to market and begin to turn a profit. Even for more
advanced drug development projects, the risk of failure in phase
III clinical trials was reported to be around 45% across all
pipelines in 2011-2020 (and over 50% for oncology trials).
41
This
means that finding a suitable and motivated purchaser for a
divested pipeline can be challenging. There are several
safeguards that can maximise the prospects of success. Firstly,
the parties can mitigate the implementation risk of the
divestment by including a so-called upfront buyer clause, as was
done in the AbbVie/Allergan case, to ensure that the main
transaction can only be implemented once the parties have found
and proposed a suitable purchaser for the pipeline and the
Commission has approved this purchaser.
42
Secondly, the
Commission routinely finds that specific purchaser criteria are
necessary to ensure that the buyer of pharmaceutical assets has
the capabilities to develop, obtain approvals for and
commercialise the products successfully.
43
Thirdly, as in other
sectors, the Commission places considerable weight on a robust
market test of a proposed remedy, to capitalise on pharma
stakeholders’ expertise to identify the remedy’s prospects of
effectively resolving the concerns, as well as potential
shortcomings.
44
Another particularity of the sector is the prevalence of
partnerships, which have led to less traditional structural
remedies. Pharmaceutical partnerships take various forms, such
as co-development, co-marketing, or licensing agreements, which
enable pharmaceutical companies to share the risks and costs of
R&D (knowing that only a small proportion of candidate drugs
will ultimately reach the market) as well as to maximise sales by
relying on the global or regional distribution capabilities of others.
In some merger cases, such competitive links gave rise to
horizontal overlaps that carried the risk that the merged entity
may compete less vigorously with its partner, or vice versa. To
resolve these concerns, the Commission has in the past accepted
remedies to prevent the merged entity from having the ability or
incentive to discontinue its own pipelines or projects with its
partners. For example, in Novartis/GSK Oncology, Novartis had
exclusively licensed the right to develop a particular pipeline from
Array, which was in phase III clinical trials and overlapped with
GSK’s marketed drug. The Commission found that this overlap
was likely to lead to discontinuation of the pipeline, so Novartis
committed to return these rights to Array (as well as divesting an
40
M.9461 AbbVie/Allergan, Commission decision of 10 January 2020.
41
Clinical Development Success Rates and Contributing Factors 2011
2020’, joint report by BIO, Informa, QLS dated 17 February 2021.
42
See, for example, M.9461 AbbVie/Allergan, Commission decision of 10
January 2020.
43
See, for example, M.9274 GlaxoSmithKline/Pfizer Consumer Healthcare
Business, Commission decision of 10 July 2019 and M.9461
AbbVie/Allergan, Commission decision of 10 January 2020.
44
Commission Remedies Notice, paragraphs 12, 15-16.
Assessing Innovation Competition in Pharma Mergers | Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
22
additional Novartis pipeline that was being developed as a
combination treatment with Array’s pipeline).
45
Similarly, in
J&J/Actelion, the commitments required the merged entity to
divest its minority shareholding in a partner company whose
activities overlapped with those of the merged entity, as well as
restricting the parties’ access to competitively sensitive
information from this partner. The parties also committed to
waive the merged entity’s royalty rights over a pipeline run by the
partner company.
46
This removed the merged entity’s influence
over its partners strategic decisions, as well as its incentive to
negatively influence the development of its own research
programmes, thereby avoiding the risk of discontinuation of the
merged entity’s or its rivals’ pipelines.
The above safeguards mean that the remedies accepted by the
Commission in pharmaceutical cases are robust. Nevertheless,
the inherent uncertainties in the multi-year, multi-million (or
billion) euro process of developing new pipelines means that
unforeseen circumstances can arise. Pharmaceutical mergers are
therefore one field where the Commission has had to resort in
exceptional circumstances to the flexibility of the review clause
to waive, modify or substitute the commitments.
47
Such waivers
are exceptional and must only be accepted if market
circumstances have changed significantly and permanently.
This was the case following the Commission’s conditional
approval of the Takeda/Shire deal.
48
To resolve the identified
concerns, Takeda committed to divest Shire’s pipeline for treating
ulcerative colitis and Crohn’s disease, including the right to
develop and commercialise the product. The market test indicated
that there was strong interest in acquiring the pipeline and
confirmed its viability and competitiveness. However, shortly
after the conditional clearance decision, the pipeline faced major
setbacks including significant challenges in recruiting patients for
the planned clinical trials, problematic results from clinical trials
that indicated higher than foreseen risks in certain patient
populations and the emergence of a novel and more promising
treatment pipeline. These issues meant that the product would
reach the market many years later than anticipated, likely in a
very different competitive landscape and would compete less
closely with Takeda’s product than anticipated in the decision.
These issues also significantly diminished any interest from
potential purchasers. These factors, which only developed after
the conditional clearance decision, cumulatively meant there was
a significant and permanent change in the market, which could
not have been foreseen at the time of the approval and which
removed the serious doubts the Commission had regarding the
transaction. Accordingly, the Commission waived the commitment
45
M.7275 Novartis/GSK Oncology, Commission decision of 28 January
2015. The commitments were conditional on Array entering a
cooperation agreement with a suitable partner that would assist it to
finalise the development and roll out the global marketing of the
products in question, otherwise a divestiture trustee would sell the
assets to an alternative suitable purchaser.
46
M.8401 J&J/Actelion, Commission decision of 9 June 2017.
47
See further Commission Remedies Notice, paragraphs 71-76.
48
M.8955 Takeda/Shire, Commission decision of 20 November 2018.
to divest the product and the merged entity discontinued the
product, while making its trial data and biosamples publicly
available to promote R&D. This reflects that pharmaceutical drug
development does carry risk, a fact which is reflected in the
safeguards adopted by the Commission, and its pragmatic
approach to addressing unforeseeable market changes following
its decisions.
Finally, it must be noted that while the Commission’s practice for
remedies in the pharmaceutical sector is well-established, it is
essential that each case and proposed remedy be assessed on its
own merits. While the time-to-market for pharmaceutical
products is long, the pace of medical innovation and new
discovery is rapid and investment in the sector is high. As a result,
there can be many promising pipelines and shifts in the prospects
of treating particular diseases. Proposed remedies must therefore
be assessed with care and with specific regard to the prevailing
medical and commercial wisdom, in view of the evidence and the
feedback provided by informed market participants, to prevent
competitive harm. This was well illustrated in the Illumina/GRAIL
case, where the proposed behavioural remedies (consisting of an
attempt to enable upstream entry and provide non-discriminatory
treatment for downstream rivals) were found insufficient to
address the competition concerns and avoid the competitive
harm arising from the transaction, resulting in its prohibition.
49
5. Jurisdictional aspects in pharma
mergers
Undertakings must notify concentrations that meet the EUMR’s
turnover thresholds to the Commission prior to their
implementation. This normally applies to concentrations in the
pharmaceutical sector where parties have both marketed drugs
generating turnover, in addition to any pipeline developments.
However, acquisitions of companies that do not yet have any
turnover but may in fact have (potentially competing) pipeline
products would not be caught by the turnover-based thresholds,
and as such, a potential enforcement gap was identified.
In 2016, the Commission launched an evaluation on the
functioning of certain procedural and jurisdictional aspects of EU
merger control, covering inter alia the effectiveness of the
turnover based notification thresholds. The Commission found
that while, on the whole, the existing thresholds work well, there
has been an increasing phenomenon of concentrations involving
firms that generate little or no turnover at the time of the
transaction but that already play or may develop into a
significant competitive role on the market. These mergers would
not be captured by the existing notification thresholds but could
have a significant impact on competition. This is particularly
relevant for the pharmaceutical sector, where innovation is a key
parameter of competition and so targets with promising drug
pipelines can have high valuations and significant competitive
potential, even if they do not generate any turnover at the time
49
M.10188 Illumina/GRAIL, Commission decision of 6 September 2022
(not yet published).
Assessing Innovation Competition in Pharma Mergers | Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
23
of the transaction and therefore fall below the relevant merger
control thresholds.
50
In light of these findings, the Commission revised its approach to
requests for case referrals under Article 22 EUMR. This provision
empowers Member States to request that the Commission
examine any concentration that lacks an EU dimension and is
therefore not directly notifiable to the Commission, provided that
it: (i) affects trade between Member States; and (ii) threatens to
significantly affect competition within the territory of the Member
State making the referral request. Other EU Member States and
EEA EFTA States may then join the initial referral request.
51
The
Commission’s jurisdiction under Article 22 is limited to examining
the effects of the transaction in the referring Member States. In
the past, the Commission had discouraged Member States from
requesting referrals in cases where they do not themselves have
jurisdiction, as it was considered, based on experience at the
time, that the national thresholds, often turnover-based, captured
all transactions that could materially impact the internal market.
However, following the results of the evaluation, the Commission
considered that referrals by Member States were an appropriate
and proportionate tool to capture below-threshold transactions
that could give rise to competition issues of the nature identified
in the consultation. Accordingly, in September 2020 the Executive
Vice-President for Competition announced that the Commission
was revising its approach, such that, in appropriate
circumstances, the Commission would henceforth encourage
Member States to refer certain cases to it even where the
transaction was not notifiable to the Member State(s) in
question.
52
Following the publication of its evaluation of procedural and
jurisdictional aspects of EU merger control identifying a potential
enforcement gap,
53
in March 2021 the Commission adopted a
guidance paper introducing a reappraisal of the application of
Article 22 to ensure that certain categories of cross-border
transactions with potentially significant impact on competition in
the internal market are appropriately examined.
54
Under this
guidance, the Commission intends to encourage and accept
referrals of transactions: (i) over which the referring Member
State does not have initial jurisdiction; and (ii) which involve firms
that play or may develop into playing a significant competitive
50
See Communication from the Commission - Guidance on the
application of the referral mechanism set out in Article 22 of the EU
Merger Regulation to certain categories of cases, 26 March 2022,
C(2021) 1959 final, paragraphs 9-12.
51
According to Article 6(3) of Protocol 24 of the EEA Agreement, one or
more EEA EFTA States (i.e., Iceland, Liechtenstein and Norway) may join
a request for referral made by a Member State under Article 22 if the
concentration affects trade between one or more EU Member States
and one or more EEA EFTA States and threatens to significantly affect
competition within the territory of the EEA ETFA State joining the
request.
52
See Speech by EVP Vestager, The future of EU merger control”, 11
September 2020, SPEECH/20/2884.
53
Evaluation of procedural and jurisdictional aspects of EU merger
control, SWD(2021) 66 final, 26.3.2021.
54
Guidance on the application of the referral mechanism set out in
Article 22 of the Merger Regulation to certain categories of cases
(2021/C 113/01), (“Article 22 Guidance” or “Guidance”).
role on the market(s) at stake despite generating little or no
turnover at the time of the concentration.
This approach has been confirmed by the EU General Court
concerning the Illumina/GRAIL decision
55
by which the
Commission accepted Article 22 referrals from six EEA States
56
regarding a concentration that was not notifiable at national level
in any EEA State.
57
The General Court’s judgment is under appeal
before the European Court of Justice.
58
Even when a referral
request fulfils the substantive and procedural
59
conditions of
Article 22, the Commission has discretion to accept or reject the
referral request. The Commission exercises this discretion based
on the principles of the Referral Notice
60
and the more recent
Article 22 Guidance.
61
As explained in the Commission’s Referral Notice, when
considering whether to accept a referral request, the Commission
will consider, e.g., the need to ensure effective protection of
competition in all markets affected by the concentration.
The Article 22 Guidance complements the Referral Notice and
adds a new category of cases generally deemed most
appropriate for an Article 22 referral. These are concentrations
where the turnover of at least one of the undertakings concerned
does not reflect its actual or future competitive potential, for
instance because the target is a start-up or recent entrant with
significant competitive potential or an important innovator or has
access to competitive significant assets such as raw materials,
infrastructure, data or intellectual property rights.
62
The Guidance
foresees that the recalibrated approach to Article 22 could be of
particular relevance to the pharmaceutical sector, due to the
importance of innovation as a parameter of competition.
Accordingly, the Guidance provides hypothetical examples of
transactions that could be considered as suitable candidates for
55
Case T-227/21 Illumina v Commission, EU:T:2022:447, judgment of
13 July 2022, paragraphs 85-184. Appeal of the judgment is pending
before the European Court of Justice, Case C-611/22 P Illumina v
Commission.
56
While only EU Member States can make the initial referral request
under Article 22 EUMR, EEA EFTA States may join the initial request.
See footnote 51 above.
57
M.10188 Illumina/GRAIL, Commission decisions of 19 April 2021
pursuant to Article 22(3) (not yet published). The initial referral by
France was joined by Belgium, Greece, Iceland, the Netherlands, and
Norway.
58
Case C-611/22 P, Illumina v Commission.
59
Referral requests are to be submitted within a period of 15 working
days of the date on which the concentration was either notified; or if it
was not notifiable nationally, otherwise made known to the Member
State concerned. In Illumina/GRAIL, the General Court confirmed the
Commission approach that “made known” should be understood to
imply an “active transmission of information” to the Member State
concerned to enable a preliminary assessment as to the existence of
the criteria relevant for the assessment of the referral. See Case T-
227/21 Illumina v Commission, paragraphs 200-213.
60
Commission Notice on Case Referral in respect of concentrations
(2005/C 56/02) (“Referral Notice”).
61
See fn. [54] above.
62
Article 22 Guidance, paragraphs 19-20. See also Practical information
on implementation of the “Guidance on the application of the referral
mechanism set out in Article 22 of the Merger Regulation to certain
categories of cases”, Frequently Asked Questions and Answers (Q&A),
available on the Commission’s website at: https://competition-
policy.ec.europa.eu/system/files/2022-
12/article22_recalibrated_approach_QandA.pdf.
Assessing Innovation Competition in Pharma Mergers | Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
24
an Article 22 referral. These include an acquisition by an active
pharmaceutical player of an innovative pharmaceutical company
with no actual revenues but an advanced pipeline project which
could target the same disease and have a comparable mode of
action as an already commercialised drug of the acquirer.
63
Other factors that the Commission may consider under the
recalibrated approach to Article 22 include whether the
consideration paid by the purchaser is particularly high compared
to the target’s current turnover which could indicate that it does
not reflect its actual or future competitive potential; potential
ongoing/parallel reviews by Member States which may
undermine the ‘one-stop-shop’ principle; and potential period of
time elapsed since the implementation of the transaction.
64
The Commission applied this approach for the first time to the
Illumina/GRAIL transaction which, due to the target being a start-
up, did not trigger a notification anywhere in the EEA. The
Commission accepted an initial referral request from France and
joining referrals from five other EU/EEA countries, none of which
had jurisdiction to review the transaction based on their national
legislation.
65
In addition to finding that the referrals met the legal
criteria of Article 22, the Commission considered a set of
additional factors in favour of accepting the referrals. These
included: (i) the fact that the value of the deal was particularly
high compared to the turnover of the target at the time of the
transaction; (ii) the fact that, while the target did not generate
revenues from the sale of products, one of its products in
development was expected to capture a significant share of the
addressable market; and (iii) the consideration that an EU-level
coordination of investigative efforts was desirable given that the
transaction concerned cancer detection, a priority of the
Commission in the area of health.
66
Finally, although pharmaceutical mergers are a key target area
for the recalibrated application of Article 22, EU Member States
retain discretion in deciding what concentrations they may refer
to the Commission. The aim of the current approach is to permit
EU Member States and the Commission to ensure that
transactions that merit review under the EUMR are examined by
the Commission, without imposing a notification obligation on
transactions that would not warrant such review. In order to
achieve this aim, the Commission is actively monitoring
transactions in the pharmaceutical sector in order to consider
their suitability for referral under Article 22 by sending requests
for information to and receiving briefing papers from the parties
to transactions that may warrant a review by the Commission on
that basis and encouraging companies to actively reach out to
request a consultation in case of doubt.
The recalibrated Article 22 policy has proven to be a necessary
and effective mechanism, working as a safety net in permitting
the Commission to screen concentrations which are likely to
significantly impede effective competition in the internal market
63
Practical information on implementation of the “Guidance on the
application of the referral mechanism set out in Article 22 of the
Merger Regulation to certain categories of cases”, Frequently Asked
Questions and Answers (Q&A), available on the Commission’s website
at: https://competition-policy.ec.europa.eu/system/files/2022-
12/article22_recalibrated_approach_QandA.pdf.
64
Article 22 Guidance, paragraphs 21-22.
65
See fn. [57] above.
66
Ibid.
and which, because the turnover thresholds have not been met,
could otherwise escape a review by the Commission and Member
States.
More generally, referral mechanisms of the EUMR may be
relevant to merger enforcement in the pharmaceutical sector, as
the existence of EEA-wide or global markets for pipeline products
may speak in favour of a review by the Commission. By way of
example, in 2019, the Commission accepted referrals to review
the proposed acquisition by J&J of Tachosil, a competing provider
of certain haemostatic and tissue sealing products
67
. The
Commission’s review raised concerns that although Johnson &
Johnson did not sell the overlapping products (dual haemostatic
patches) in the EEA at the time of the transaction, it had done so
until 2017 and at the time of the transaction sold them outside
the EEA. The Commission's investigation revealed that absent the
transaction, Johnson & Johnson would have had strong incentives
to enter EEA markets either with the product it was marketing
outside the EEA or with new product that it might have developed
absent the transaction. The Commission initiated an in-depth
investigation, and the parties abandoned the transaction before
the Commission could reach its final decision.
68
More recently,
Pfizer/Seagen
69
was referred to the Commission under
Article 4(5) EUMR.
6. International cooperation
Taking into account the global nature of large pharmaceutical
mergers and the fact that innovation markets are often deemed
to be global, cooperation between the competition enforcers is of
paramount importance when assessing mergers with innovation
elements. Such cooperation is conducted on a case-by-case basis
for investigations where multiple competition authorities are
involved and the merging parties have provided a waiver allowing
authorities to discuss confidential information. Allowing for
cooperation between the authorities often leads to positive
outcomes for the parties as investigations may be more aligned
in terms of timing and, where relevant, remedies. In March 2021,
at policy level, the Commission, together with the Canadian
Competition Bureau, the UK's Competition and Markets Authority,
the U.S. Federal Trade Commission (FTC), U.S. Department of
Justice, and three U.S. Offices of Attorneys General launched a
multilateral working group to analyse the effects of mergers in
the pharmaceutical sector. The working group was initiated by the
FTC and is in line with close cooperation between national
competition authorities.
70
The working group’s efforts culminated
in a workshop on 14-15 June 2022, in which the participating
competition authorities and sector experts contributed their
experiences, views and approaches to pharmaceutical merger
enforcement, focusing on innovation aspects of pharmaceutical
mergers, amongst other issues, such as price competition and
remedies.
71
67
M.9547 Johnson & Johnson / Tachosil (withdrawn on 8 April 2020).
68
Withdrawal of notification of a concentration (Case M.9547 Johnson
& Johnson/Tachosil) 2020/C 124/01.
69
M.11177 Pfizer/Seagen, Commission decision of 19 October 2023 (not
yet published).
70
See Commission press release:
https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/IP_21_1203.
71
See FTC-DOJ Workshop Summary: The Future of Pharma (ftc.gov).
Assessing Innovation Competition in Pharma Mergers | Competition Policy Brief No 1/2024
25
Conclusion
The pharmaceutical industry is innovative by nature. Accordingly,
innovation plays a key role in merger reviews in the
pharmaceutical sector, as it is relevant not only for the
substantive assessment but is also a relevant parameter when
considering jurisdiction.
The Commission has developed its analytical approach to
innovation in pharmaceutical cases over time, applying its
assessment framework in multiple decisions. This framework
gives certainty over the analytical approach the Commission will
use, while allowing for the necessary flexibility required to assess
complex innovation theories of harm and potentially remedies
based on the relevant facts of each case. The work of the
multilateral working group focusing on pharma indicates that
competition agencies globally are seeking to develop and improve
assessment of innovation aspects of pharmaceutical mergers.